By Eric Vandenbroeck and
co-workers
From Chile To Mexico
While the collapse of
Argentina's economy in 2001-2 attracted horrified glances, Colombia's drug
lords and guerrilla violence still made headlines-- while Fidel Castro remained
a curiosity, stubbornly ensconced in his communist island well into old age,
having seen off nine American presidents. Then, suddenly, the veil of oblivion
thrown over Latin America by much of the media in Europe and the United States
parted. Presidential elections in a dozen countries in the thirteen months from
November 2005 aroused a flurry of outside interest. This mainly focussed on the notion that Latin America was moving irrevocably
to the left and out from under the thumb of the United States, where it was
asserted to have forever languished. Much of the interest was catalysed by Hugo Chavez, Venezuela's voluble populist
president, and by his search for disciples in the region. He aroused fears in
many quarters (and hopes in others) that he might be another Castro - but one
armed with oil.
But the recent
U.S.-Venezuelan energy disagreements such as the PDVSA-ExxonMobil legal dispute
are more for political show than anything else. Chavez wants to demonstrate
that his country is not reliant on U.S. oil revenues and signal to the world
that its national energy company is capable of standing up against its U.S.
counterparts. But as long as the United States remains the most profitable
export destination for Venezuelan oil, Chavez’s threats remain empty. And he
needs the money to buy support at home.
Visiting Chile And Beyond
Twenty years ago, the
Casablanca valley was a dusty place of sleepy farms through which traffic
crawled on a narrow road linking Santiago, Chile’s capital, with Valparaiso,
its largest port. Today, the valley floor is carpeted with mile after mile of
trim vineyards. They produce good quality white wine, in a country which until
recently had been known in the world only for cheap but reliable vino tinto. A fast new toll motorway snakes through the valley
and over the dun-coloured hills to the coast. It was
built and maintained by private investment under a public-private partnership.
Beside the motorway stands an unobtrusive white building that houses the
laboratory of Vitro Centre Chile. Opened in 2004, the laboratory turns out
partially fattened lily bulbs using up-to-date biotechnology. It is a joint
venture among local private investors, a Dutch firm and Fundacion Chile, a
public-private technology agency. It began on a small scale, employing 43
people. But its founders hoped to be exporting lily bulbs to Holland within a
few years, competing for a slice of a $750 million world market, and to have
established a new high-tech flower-export business! If they succeed, they will
follow a long line of new export industries created in Chile in recent decades,
such as fish-farming, wine, fruit and furniture. The country is making a
successful living out of its natural resources, partly by adding value to them.
The Chilean Model: Reform Deepened By Democracy
Uniquely in Latin
America, Chile has achieved sustained and rapid economic growth over the past
two decades, and as a result has seen poverty fall sharply. Over that period
(1987-2006) its economy grew at an annual average rate of 6 per cent. The
equivalent figure for Latin America as a whole was just 2.8 per cent. Even in
1998 to 2003, when the rest of Latin America stalled, Chile still managed to
grow at an annual average of 2.8 per cent - once again more than twice the
regional rate. From 2004 onwards, growth has returned to an annual rate of
around 4 to 5 per cent. Keep it up, and in another decade or so Chile will have
achieved developed country status, with a similar income per head to Portugal,
Greece or Spain today.2 True, income distribution in Chile is much more unequal
than in those countries. But poverty has fallen sharply, from a peak of 45 per
cent of the population in the mid-198oS to 19 per cent by 2004 and 13.7 per
cent by 2006.
It is an
uncomfortable fact for democrats that the foundations of Chile's dynamic
export-led growth we,r.e laid by General Pinochet -
but only through a costly process of trial and error. Shortly after seizing
power Pinochet entrusted the economy to the 'Chicago Boys', a group of
neo-conservative economists trained at the University of Chicago. They implemented
a drastic adjustment, which saw the fiscal deficit fall from 25 per cent of GDP
in 1973 to 1 per cent in 1975, and a radical programme
of structural reform. This included large-scale privatisation
(though the copper and oil firms were kept in state hands), and the opening of
a previously closed economy. Import tariffs were cut from an average of 110 per
cent in 1973 to 14 per cent by 1979, and all restrictions on the financial
system lifted. The Chicago Boys ignored the short-term social cost of their
policies. They also made policy mistakes. In privatising,
they paid no heed to competition or regulation. The result was that the economy
came to be dominated by a clutch of highly indebted conglomerates centred on the privatised banks.3
This mistake was compounded by a second one. Worried that inflation was slow to
fall, in 1978 the government fixed the exchange rate. The peso quickly became
overvalued, prompting an import boom and allowing the conglomerates to borrow
dollars cheaply abroad. In 1982, Chile went bust, hit harder by the debt crisis
than any other Latin American country. The economy shrank by 14 per cent. In
1983, real wages fell more than 10 per cent and unemployment climbed to 30 per
cent (including people on a government make-work programme).
The financial system collapsed, and was re-nationalised.
The bank bailout would lumber the government with liabilities equivalent to 35
per cent of GDP.
In its aftermath, a
new economic team implemented more pragmatic, gradualist policies. Tariffs were
temporarily raised, some prices were indexed and inflation would not reach
single figures until 1995. To prevent overvaluation of the exchange rate, which
was pegged close to inflation, the government imposed a tax on short-term
capital inflows. A second round of privatisation,
which included the utilities and the pension system, was carried out with more
attention to regulation. Growth resumed, and this time it was sustained. The
reforms had worked - but they took much longer to do so than their authors had
assumed. By the early 1990S, Chile could be hailed as a 'textbook example of an
open economy'.
The governments of
the centre-left Concertacion
coalition that have ruled Chile since 1990 kept the broad thrust of the
dictatorship's economic policies, deepened some of them and reformed others.
That bestowed democratic legitimacy on the 'Chilean model'. Since 1990, income
per head has more than doubled. Growth has remained high but has been less
volatile than under the dictatorship. It has been driven by exports and by
investment. In 1970, exports were equal to just 12 per cent of Chile's GDP; in
2005, that figure was 41 per cent. In the 15 years to 2003, exports almost
quintupled, while the share accounted for by copper fell from 86 per cent in
the 1960s to 40 to 50 per cent. Under Ricardo Lagos, a moderate socialist who
was president from 2000 to 2006, Chile deepened its commitment to open trade,
signing free-trade agreements with the United States, the European Union and
South Korea. From the late 1980s onwards, the rate of investment climbed
steadily to reach around 25 per cent of GDP, well above the regional average.
Uniquely in the region, most of this investment has been financed by an
increase in national savings, which rose from 8 per cent of GDP in 1985 to 27.1
per cent a decade later. Those savings came partly from a consistent budget
surplus, partly from the privatisation of the pension
system by the dictatorship, but mainly from high levels of savings and
investment by business, encouraged by a 1984 reform which cut taxes on
re-invested profits.s The Concertacion
governments placed greater emphasis on social policy, partly to repair the lack
of social investment by the dictatorship and partly to try to reduce
inequality. Their approach has been cautious. In 2004, public spending in Chile
was only 22 per cent of GDP - the same share as in 1987, pointed out Nicolas
Eyzaguirre, a Harvardeducated former IMF official who
was Lagos's finance minister.6 But rapid growth and a reduction in military
spending meant, for example, that spending on education tripled in the decade
after 1990. Under a government-backed housing programme,
campamentos (shantytowns) were all but eliminated.
Lagos set out to abolish extreme poverty in Chile, through a programme called Chile Solidario.
His government also introduced unemployment insurance. The Concertacion
governments drew on private investment, operating under public contracts, to
upgrade the country's infrastructure. More than 2,000 kilometres
of motorways were built, and airport capacity tripled?
What explains Chile's
remarkable success? The first factor, without doubt, is effective economic
policies. These assign clear roles to market and state. 'The market is
essential for growth and democracy is essential for governance,' as Lagos has
put it.8 Under the Concertacion, the state has
concentrated on regulating markets, rather than intervening in them. Fiscal
policy has long been prudent, and has become increasingly sophisticated. In
contrast to Venezuela, Chile saves in a 'stabilisation
fund' part of its windfall when copper revenues are high. As a result, alone in
the region Chile was able to increase social spending during the recession
(mild in its case) of 2000 to 2002, enabling it to break with its past cycles
of boom and bust. Lagos codified this counter-cyclical fiscal policy in a rule.
This requires the government to record a fiscal surplus of 1 per cent when the
economy is growing at its potential (as defined by an independent panel of
experts) and when the copper price is at its expected long-term average (as
forecast by a second panel). If either figure is below par, the government can
spend more. The surplus required under the rule is in part to defr~y the liabilities from the 1982 banking collapse.9
This fiscal rigour means tnat
public debt stood at just 12 per cent of GDP at the end of 2004, and has given
Chile Latin America's best credit rating and some of its lowest interest rates.
As the copper price went through the roof in 2005 and 2006, the government once
again faced the challenge of trying to prevent the peso from appreciating too
much. The response was characteristic. The administration of Michelle Bachelet,
who succeeded Lagos as president in March 2006, announced that on top of the
existing copperstabilisation fund, it planned to set
aside an amount equal to about 0.5 per cent of GDP per year in a
pension-guarantee fund whose proceeds will be invested abroad.lO
But fiscal rigour and respect for markets has been
combined with a dose of pragmatism - and even heterodoxy. The dictatorship did
not privatise Codelco, the state-owned firm which is
the world's largest copper producer, partly because some of its profits went to
the armed forces for arms purchases. The Concertaci6n governments have kept
Codelco in state hands, but encouraged private (including foreign) investment
in new mines and reduced the proportion of its profits spent on arms.
Similarly, the controls on capital inflows were counter to IMF orthodoxy, but
are now widely accepted to have helped Chile avoid financial instability (they
were abolished when the Central Bank adopted a floating exchange rate in 1998).
As important as the
policies themselves is the broad political consensus that sustains them. This
was forged in negotiations over the transition to democracy after Pinochet lost
a 1988 referendum on staying in power. From this consensus derives policy stability.
In Chile, unlike in many other countries in the region, businesses can afford
to make long-term investments, knowing that political surprises are highly
unlikely. That applies equally to private investment in infrastructure, and
explains why Chile has the most modern network of roads, ports and airports of
anywhere in the region. This policy environment eventually spawned a dynamic
business class in Chile, helped by deep capital markets. Though foreign
investment is welcome, Chile is notable for a large number of home-grown
companies, many of which have begun to invest in other Latin American
countries.
A third factor is
relatively solid institutions, such as the civil service and courts - a legacy
of the country's long tradition of constitutionalism and the Chilean democracy
has become increasingly self-confident. For much of the 1990S, the Concertacion coalition had to govern in the shadow of
Pinochet and his supporters, who exercised much influence over the army,
business and the media. More than in most countries, the transition to
democracy was a negotiation. Under this deal, Pinochet stayed on as army
commander for seven years, the civilian government was saddled with a
military-dominated national security council, and former military commanders
were among nine appointed senators who gave the conservative opposition a veto
over constitutional change. Pinochet';'- arrest in London in 1998, at the
request of a Spanish court, proved to be a turning point. It emboldened Chile's
judiciary to unpick parts of the amnesty that the dictatorship had granted
itself for its abuses of human rights. By January 2005 some 300 retired
officers, including 21 generals, were in jail or facing charges.15 Lagos was
both willing and able to adopt a more robust attitude than his two elected
predecessors to making Chile 'a democracy above suspicion' as he put it. In
2005 the conservative opposition finally agreed to scrap the authoritarian
clauses in the constitution. In other ways, too, Chile has become a palpably
more relaxed place. The Lagos government pushed through laws abolishing the
death penalty and film censorship, and legalising
divorce (though abortion remains prohibited, even in cases where the mother has
been raped or her life is endangered by the pregnancy). Talking in La Moneda,
the palace where Allende had fallen, Lagos pointed to 'a wider cultural change
in Chilean society' and 'a greater openness'.16
These changes were symbolised by the election of Michelle Bachelet as
president in 2006. A paediatrician in her fifties,
Bachelet came originally from the left wing of the Socialist Party and had
spent part of her exile in East Germany. The main difference between her and
Lagos was in her relative lack of political experience. As a candidate, she
seemed hesistant on policy issues. But when asked
about her life and how Chileans see her, she became animated, a note of passion
entering her voice. Bachelet's father was an air force general who sympathised with Allende. He died of a heart attack while
in prison after the coup; both she and her mother were briefly detained and
ill-treated in Villa Grimaldi, the headquarters of the DINA, Pinochet's
notorious intelligence agency, before going into exile in Australia and then
East Germany. Rather than her socialist politics, what made her election
remarkable in a country long held to be the most socially conservative in Latin
America was that she is an agnostic and has three children by two different
men, neither of whom she lives with. 'The polls show that more than half of
Chileans think I'm the person who best represents Chile,' Bachelet said. 'I
have a different sort of family, but one that is similar to a third of Chilean
families.' 17 In her first year in office, Bachelet looked less than assured.
She handed economic policy over to a competent American-educated team, but with
only a couple of exceptions her first cabinet was as inexperienced as she was.
She proclaimed her intention to promote a 'citizens' democracy,' with greater
public participation in policymaking. But in May and June 2006, her government
was shaken by protests by school students, backed by many parents and teachers,
over the poor quality of education. It was the biggest display of discontent
since the end of the dictatorship. With the state's coffers overflowing with
record copper revenues, the protestors demanded that the government breach its
fiscal rules and spend more on schools.18 Yet the problem of education is as
much one of management as of lack of money. The government stood firm, at some
cost to its popularity.
Such disagreements
are the lifeblood of a normal democracy - which is what Chile has at last
become. Purists might argue that its transition to democracy will not be
complete until there has been alternation of power. That is partly because some
Chileans will remain unconvinced that the conservative opposition has itself
embraced democracy, as Franco's supporters in Spain's Popular Party did. Yet
one can hardly blame the government for not losing an election. Not only does
Chile's democracy now look consolidated. Its combination of market and state,
growth and social policies, stands as a more powerful and effective example to
the region than Chavez's sound and fury. Lagos, in particular, repeatedly tried
to distinguish Chile's path both from events elsewhere in the region and from
the neo-conservative policies of his country's recent past. 'How much of what
we are seeing in Latin America is related to the simplistic belief of a few
people that distribution can only occur in the context of populism? In our experience
this will end in failure in the long-run. And how many others think that growth
is enough, and the rest will come naturally?' 19 Of course, some of the factors
in Chile's success were not easily exportable. But other countries, such as
Peru - another open economy based on mining and export agriculture - have
adopted elements of them.
Brazil: Reform Through Democracy
Mention Chile, a
country of just 15 million people, in mighty Brazil, and you will be greeted
with derision. Brazil has followed its own path towards development over the
past dozen years but like that of Chile over the same period it has been marked
by democratic pragmatism. After a decade of false starts, with the Real Plan of
1993-4 Brazil finally began to rganized its economy
and embarked on rganized reforms of the kind adopted
earlier elsewhere in the region. Reform in Brazil has been slow and incremental,
democratic and consensual. It has involved bottom-up institution-building
rather than top-down dictation. By 2006 there were fears that the reformist
momentum had been lost. But what has been achieved looks more solid than in
some other countries.20
There were several
reasons why reform came late to Brazil. Unlike, say, Argentina, Brazil enjoyed
rapid and almost uninterrupted economic growth for three decades until 1980.
And unlike Argentina, Brazil had found ways of living with inflation, chiefly by
rganized indexation under which wages, prices, debt
payments and so on were adjusted automatically for past price increases. It was
an eff~ctive but insidious system which aggravated
inequality. Inflation rose steadily, but the annual rate only broke into three
figures in 1980 and into four figures in 1988. ‘Inflation gave to many people
(but not to the great mass of poor Brazilians) the illusion of abundance,’
noted Fernando Henrique Cardoso, who would eventually end it.21 Another
delaying factor was that the 1982 debt crisis and the economy’s subsequent
stutters coincided with a protracted – and accident-prone – transition from
dictatorship to democracy. The generals and their supporters allowed free
elections for state governors in 1982, but then snubbed a popular campaign for
a direct election for president three years later. That ensured that the first
civilian federal government in two decades would be weak. Tragically, it was
weakened further when Tancredo Neves, the leader of the opposition party of the
Brazilian Democratic Movement (PM DB) and the man chosen as president by the
Congress, died before he could take office. His vice-president, Jose Sarney,
took over, but as a longstanding supporter of the military regime who had
switched sides at the last moment, he lacked Neves’s legitimacy. The election
in 1989 of Fernando Collor de Melo, a young telegenic politician from the
backward north-eastern state of Alagoas, proved to be another false start. His
technically flawed rganizedn plan failed. His
high-handed treatment of Congress backfired; he resigned to avoid impeachment
for corruption. His only lasting achievements were to have slashed import
tariffs and begun to privatise the state’s vast
holdings. He was replaced by his vice-president, Itamar Franco, an
undistinguished PMDB politician from Minas Gerais.
A third problem was
that reform in a federal democracy is inevitably slow and complex. Brazil is
simply too large and diverse ever to be a ‘delegative democracy’ in which the
president can decree far-reaching change from the rg
With the brief exception of Vargas’s Estado Novo, Brazil has always resisted
absolutism: it is not coincidental that its monarchy was a constitutional one,
and that its dictatorship of 1964-85 chose to keep the Congress in being and
limited its military presidents to fixed six-year terms. To make matters even
more difficult for reformers, Brazil’s fledgling democracy equipped itself with
a new constitution in 1988 which was riddled with flaws. It entrenched the
failing economic model of statist nationalism and corporatist privilege just
when this was going out of fashion across the world. It even included a
constitutional cap on interest rates, at 12 per cent – a provision inevitably honoured in the breach. It gave all those who had worked in
the public sector for five years absolute job tenure and full pension rights
even though they had not sat competitive exams. As politicians rushed to
exercise their new scope for patronage, federal government spending on
personnel increased from 2.5 per cent of GDP in 1986 to 4.5 per cent in 1989.23
The constitution was drawn
up at a time when the federal executive was weak, both in relation to the
Congress and to the directly elected state governors and mayors who secured an
exaggerated devolution of power and money, free from corresponding
responsibilities. Cardoso, a senator in the Constituent Congress, later said
that this body ‘reminded me a lot of my time [teaching at the University of
Paris] in Nanterre in May 1968 when it was forbidden to forbid’.24 In reaction
to the dictatorship’s shackles on political parties, the politicians in
Brasilia rejected any rules that might impose party discipline on legislators.
But they kept the gross over-representation of poorer and more backward
northern and north-eastern states introduced by the generals to diminish the
weight of democratic and progressive opinion in Silo Paulo and the south.
Unlike other federal states, such as the United States and Germany, Brazil
allows less-populated remote areas to be over-represented not just in the
Senate but in the lower house too (as does Argentina). According to population,
Silo Paulo should have 110, rather than its current 70, seats in the Chamber of
Deputies while Roraima, on the border with Venezuela, should have just one
rather than its current eight. Over-representation of sparsely populated areas
in the Senate is even greater in Brazil than in the United States: one vote for
the senate in Roraima has equal weight to 144 votes in Silo Paulo.25 The
Congress was given the power to revise the constitution five years after it
came into effect, by simple majority rather than the normal 60 per cent vote.
But when it came, in 1993, that opportunity was not taken, because Congress was
reeling from a scandal in which members of the budget committee were found to
have taken bribes from construction companies. Of 30,000 proposed amendments,
only five were adopted.26 One of these further weakened the executive by
cutting the president’s term from five to four years.
For a dozen years
after the debt crisis broke in 1982, no government managed to rganized the economy for more than a few months and much of
the public goodwill towards the new democracy was squandered. Yet just when
Brazil appeared ungovernable in democracy, matters were in fact beginning to changeP In May 1993, Cardoso was Brazil’s foreign minister.
He was at a dinner party in New York when he received a phone call from Itamar
Franco, the eccentric interim president, who said he was thinking of making him
finance minister. The job was a poisoned chalice. Inflation would top 2,700 per
cent that year. Franco had already got through three finance ministers in seven
months. Cardoso later recalled that by the time he went to bed he thought he
had persuaded the president to desist. Franco appointed him regardless.28 It
was that ‘accident’ that would lead to Cardoso, a brilliant and cosmopolitan
sociology professor who lacked the common touch, being elected president of
Brazil for two successive terms. As finance minister, Cardoso assumed the role
of de facto prime minister. He assembled a team of talented liberal economists
who came up with the Real Plan, a clever mix of budget cuts, a new cu~rency and a mechanism to break price indexation and
inflationary expectations. According to Cardoso, ‘The root cause of inflation
in Brazil was really very simple. The government spent more than it earned.’29
The forecast federal deficit in 1994 was $20 billion of a total budget of $90
billion. Yet dealing with the problem was not simple at all. As Cardoso noted,
‘The budget was a work of fiction. The accounts of the Central Bank and the
Treasury were mixed together and nobody knew much about either of them.’ 30
Apart from budget reform, the groundwork also included putting an end to
federal ‘loans’ to state governments which were rarely repaid and renegotiating
the foreign debt.
Cardoso’s team
correctly perceived that Brazilians were fed up with inflation and would
support almost any measures to end it. They secured Congressional approval in
1993 for cuts in spending and in constitutionally mandated transfers to states
and municipalities. But unlike previous failed rganizedn
plans, the Real Plan did not involve either wage or price freezes. Its centrepiece was a ‘virtual’ currency, known as the Unit of
Real Value, which operated alongside the devalued cruzeiro for several months.
This allowed relative prices to adjust, and persuaded Brazilians that the new
currency – the real, launched on 1 July 1994 – would preserve its value. It
worked: annual inflation fell to two digits by 1995 and to under 2 per cent by
1998. Unlike many other countries in the region, Brazil vanquished inflation
without a recession. The increase in the real value of wages sparked a
consumption boom. Economic growth averaged 4 per cent a year from 1994 to 1997
despite interest rates remaining high.
Only weeks before the
launch of the real, it had seemed inevitable that Luiz Inacio Lula da Silva of
the left-wing Workers’ Party (PT), narrowly defeated by Collor in 1989, would
win the 1994 presidential election. The success of the Real Plan turned the
race upside down. Cardoso rganize that he would win
the election during a campaign stop in Santa Maria da Vit6ria, a small town in
the backlands of Bahia, in the impoverished north-east, on 11 July 1994. The
townspeople in the square held up one-real notes and asked him to autograph
them. ‘The real rescued hope and trust, not just in the currency and economic rganizedn, but in the country’, Cardoso wrote.31 While
Lula, because of his personal journey from poverty to leadership, was a symbol
in himself, Cardoso was not, and needed the symbol of the real to win. Bringing
inflation under control in itself caused a 20 per cent drop in poverty.32 Lula,
the PT and the rest of the left made the mistake of opposing the Real Plan. Its
success meant that Cardoso won the election outright with 54 per cent of the
vote. Yet achieving the new president’s goals of consolidating economic
stability, integrating Brazil’s economy with the world, rganized
the state and tackling Brazil’s social problems would involve a lengthy – and
in 2006 still unfinished – political battle.
Cardoso was the
leader of the Brazilian Social Democratic Party (PSDB), which in 1988 had
broken away from the amorphous PMDB. The PSDB, with strong support in Sao
Paulo, Minas Gerais and Ceara in particular, was a mainly middle-class party of
professionals and technocrats. It had a clearer programme
than the catch-all PMDB. Cardoso defined the PSDB as ‘a centreleft
coalition of committed democrats ... We advocated a blend offree-market
reform and social responsibility’ in the mould of
Felipe Gonzalez in Spain, Bill Clinton in the United States and Tony Blair in
Britain.33 To support Cardoso’s candidacy, the PSDB had formed a coalition with
the conservative Liberal Front Party, and with the smaller Brazilian Labour Party (PTB). In office, Cardoso invited the PMDB to
join the government. In theory, Cardoso’s government enjoyed the support of 70
per cent of the Congress, making constitutional reform easy. Yet, in practice,
changing the constitution was a Herculean task. It involved rounding up the
votes of 60 per cent of the total membership of each house of Congress. This
majority had to be rganized not just for formal votes
on constitutional bills, in two consecutive sessions of Congress, but to defeat
line-by-line amendments by opponents. Many nominal government supporters
regularly voted against it when public spending or corporatist privileges were
at stake. Ideally, the government should have moved swiftly to achieve lasting
fiscal stability by reforming the structure and financing of government at all
levels. But these tasks were complex and politically divisive.34 Instead,
Cardoso opted to give priority to more straightforward bills to roll back the
state monopolies enshrined in the constitution. In 1995, Congress approved
constitutional amendments ending the state monopolies of oil, gas distribution,
telecoms and merchant shipping, and another one to guarantee the same treatment
to foreign companies operating in Brazil as to local firms. In all, in eight
years, Cardoso’s two administrations secured the approval of thirty
constitutional amendments, most aimed at creating a modern social democratic
state and all tenaciously opposed by the PT and other, smaller, left-wing
parties.35
Yet despite these
successes, Cardoso’s governments were dogged by the difficulty of rganized political support for fiscal reform in the teeth
of myriad special interests. After the initial squeeze at the start of the Real
Plan, the budget deficit steadily rose again: the public-sector borrowing
requirement reached 8 per cent of GDP in 1998. There were several reasons, but
most came down to a characteristically Brazilian vice: for decades, the
better-off had turned the state into a device for lining their own pockets
while robbing the poor through inflation. Qnce inflation ended, the state could
no longer evade the bill for its misplaced generosity. One egregious example
was the pension system. This broke just about every rule known to actuaries.36
There was no minimum retirement age. This mattered less when life expectancy
was short. In the 1950S there were eight workers for each pensioner, but by the
1990S there were just over two. In the public sector, retirees could draw more
than one pension and carryon working as well; the retirement pension was often
higher than the final salary. By 1997 the total value of pensions paid to 2.9
million people in the public sector exceeded those paid to almost 17 million
private-sector pensioners by the National Social Security Institute (INSS). The
INSS itself went into deficit, partly because pensions went up every time the
minimum wage increased. Total federal government spending on pensions increased
from $5.5 billion in 1992 to $16 billion in 1996. The pension system was a
prime example of the way in which public spending in Brazil was skewed towards
the better-off: in 1999 the richest 20 per cent of Brazilians received 65 per
cent of government spending on pensions, while the poorest fifth got just 2.4
per cent.37 Yet a constitutional amendment that would have brought some
rationality to the system languished in Congress for years. The end of
inflation exposed a number of other ‘fiscal skeletons’ as they were called. The
government absorbed some of the debts of the states in return for their
commitments to cut payroll spending and avoid future indebtedness. It bailed
out the state-owned Banco do Brasil, the country’s
largest bank, to the tune of $8 billion. At the same time – and contrary to the
myth propagated by its critics on the left – the government expanded social
spending, which amounted to 19.1 per cent of GDP by 2002, up from 17.6 per cent
a decade earlier.38
Interviewed in his
wood-panelled office in Brasilia’s Planalto Palace in March 1999, when his government was
reeling from a forced devaluation, Cardoso admitted ruefully that if he had had
his first term again ‘I would be much more severe in controlling federal
spending and in encouraging state governors to do the same.’ 39 The price of
loose fiscal policy was that the economic team headed by Pedro Malan, the shy,
pipe-smoking finance minister from 1995 to 2001, came to rely on an overvalued
currency and high interest rates to consolidate its victory over inflation. To
make matters worse, throughout Cardoso’s two terms, Brazil was hit by periodic
bouts of financial instability, in which the price of shares and bonds would
plunge, and vast sums of money would leave the country. The origins of these
episodes was usually external: Mexico’s devaluation of 1994-5, the instability
of several East Asian countries in 1997-8, Russia’s default of 1998 and
Argentina’s collapse of 2001-‘2. But they affected Brazil badly because of its
fiscal vulnerability (which they aggravated) and because of its pegged exchange
rate. Under the system adopted in 1995, the real depreciated by some 6 per cent
a year against the dollar; by 1997, many economists reckoned it was overvalued by
about 20 per cent, and Brazil’s current-account deficit had climbed to 4.2 per
cent of GDP. When the Asian crisis hit and nervous investors began to yank
their capital out of Brazil, the Central Bank doubled its benchmark interest
rate (to a stratospheric 44 per cent) to defend the exchange rate. But this
jacked up the cost of rolling over the ever-growing public debt, which leapt
from a comfortable 28 per cent of GDP in 1995 to 44 per cent in 1998. In
January 1999, days after Cardoso had begun his second term, his government was
finally forced to float the real. After a few anxious weeks, financial order
was restored, with the help of a loan from the IMF and a skilful
new Central Bank president, Arminio Fraga, who had previously worked on Wall
Street for an investment fund operated by George Soros. To restore confidence
in the currency, the Central Bank temporarily increased interest rates again,
while the government launched a raft of fiscal measures. This worked: inflation
was contained and the economy grew in 1999, albeit by only 1 per cent. But high
interest rates and the devaluation itself pushed the public debt (much of which
was in dollars) to over 50 per cent of GDP, while interest payments on the debt
peaked at a massive 6 per cent of GDP.40
Given its cost, the
delay in devaluing the real was a matter of fierce debate in Brazil. The most
common criticism is that Cardoso gave priority to winning a second term, for
which he first had to secure Congressional support in 1997 for a constitutional
amendment to allow re-election. In his memoirs, the president himself says that
he was aware as early as 1995 of the need to loosen the exchange-rate peg. In
retrospect, he says, he should have done so in early 1998. He gives three
reasons for the failure to do so then, or at any other point in his first term.
He wanted to wait for a moment when international financial markets were calm.
His economic team was badly divided over the issue. Lastly, he argues, ‘In an
economy that was still partly indexed and with the vivid memory of decades of
inflation, the fear of a relapse into the inferno of hyperinflation tormented
us. We remained victorious and immobile.’ 41 These arguments are plausible.
Eliana Cardoso (no relation of the president), who left the economic team
because of her disagreement with the exchange-rate policy, concurred that ‘a
graceful exit strategy was simply not available ... As long as reserves and
capital flows are available, the temptation to continue to use the exchange
rate to keep inflation under control seems rganized.’
42
In the wake of the
devaluation, the government put in place a new set of macroeconomic policies.
As well as the floating exchange rate, these included targets for inflation and
for the primary fiscal surplus (i.e. before debt payments). These were underpinned
by the approval in 1999 of a Fiscal Responsibility Law, which had the status of
a constitutional measure, and which codified all the pu~lic-finance
reforms of the Cardoso era, placing strict limits on the indebtedness of all
levels of government. Months earlier, stung into action by the devaluation,
Congress at last approved two long-awaited constitutional reforms. One was a
watered-down pension reform. The other was a reform of the public
administration, which required governments at all levels to reduce their
payroll spending to 60 per cent of their revenues within two years, and allowed
them to sack workers to do so. But the devaluation had a high political cost.
Cardoso lost much of his previous popularity and his government lost the
initiative in Congress amid infighting among some of his key supporters. A
promising economic recovery was derailed in 2001, partly by a drought-induced
energy shortage and partly by the knock-on effect of Argentina’s troubles. One
final episode of financial instability lay ahead in 2002, when investors began
to worry about Lula winning the election. Their fears turned out to be
misplaced – Lula opted to maintain Cardoso’s economic policy framework. But
they were understandable given the last-minute nature of Lula’s conversion to
macroeconomic prudence.
In headline terms,
the Cardoso government’s economic record was disappointing: the economy grew at
an annual average rate of just 2.3 per cent between 1995 and 2002, while
unemployment rose from 4-4 per cent to 7.5 per cent over the same period (or to
11.2 per cent using the new, more realistic methodology adopted in 2001). Yet
conquering inflation was a historic achievement, and dealing with its aftermath
was a long and messy job. Unlike in many other Latin American countries,
devaluation was not followed by a banking crisis. That was in large part thanks
to a well-executed programme, known as PROER, which
cleaned up the banking system without bailing out miscreant or irresponsible
bank shareholders, at a net cost of just 3 per cent of GDP.43 Officials argued
plausibly that behind the disappointing growth figures lay a process of structural
change in the economy which would bear fruit in the medium term. Having
abandoned its past introversion, Brazil was becoming much more integrated with
the world. More than $170 billion in foreign direct investment poured in, much
of it attracted by a largescale rganizedn programme. The reduction in trade protectionism forced
Brazilian firms to become more efficient. Productivity, which declined in the
1980S, rose at an annual average rate of 1.1 per cent in the decade after
1994.44
The devaluation
triggered an export boom: Brazil’s exports rocketed from $51 billion in 1998 to
$137 billion in 2006, as industries as diverse as cars and agriculture rganized. Much to his annoyance, Cardoso’s opponents in the
PT sneeringly dubbed him a ‘neoliberal’. In his memoirs, he goes to great
lengths to rebut this, insisting that, ‘If we did anything in the ten years
that I was minister or president, it was to rebuild the administrative machine,
give greater consistency to public policies, in summary to remake the state.’
45 What rganizedn the Cardoso government’s refor~s was pragmatism, in which the freeing of markets was
combined with measures aimed at creating a rganized,
regulatory state. That spirit was rganized in the rganizedn of Telebras. Whereas
Mexico and Argentina had turned state telecoms monopolies into private ones,
Brazilian officials introduced competition from the outset. Similarly, the
government kept Petrobras, the oil company, in state ownership but subjected it
to market discipline by floating 40 per cent of its shares. The state retained
around a third of the banking system. The government used BNDES, the state
development bank, to pursue an industrial policy (though some would argue that
instead of rganized capital it should have spent more
on education). Cardoso also put much stress on reforming social policies. He
won approval for a constitutional amendment which obliged state and municipal
governments to boost teachers’ salaries and classroom equipment in the poorest
areas. Primary-school enrolment increased to 97 per cent of the relevant age
group, while secondary enrolment increased by 70 per cent. The government also
initiated targeted anti-poverty programmes, and a
large-scale agrarian reform that saw 80,000 families a year receive land. Yet
the economic disappointments and intermittent financial turmoil of the second
term meant that Cardoso was unable to see his chosen successor, Jose Serra, his
health minister, elected. In October 2002, at the fourth attempt, Luiz Inacio
Lula da Silva won the presidency with 53 million votes to Serra’s 33 million in
a run-off ballot.
Lula: Continuity, Change And Corruption
For Brazilian
democracy, Lula’s was a historic victory. In the country of social injustice,
his life story was a saga of triumph over adversity worthy of a telenovela. He
was the seventh child of a dirt-poor family from the northeast. Aged seven, he
made the bone shaking journey in a pau de arara (an
open-bed truck known as a ‘parrot’s perch’ because passengers must cling to an
overhead rail) to join his father who had migrated to Sao Paulo. He was the
first in his family to complete primary school, but his formal education went
no further. After a series of odd jobs, he entered a government training
scheme, becoming a lathe operator at a metalbashing
firm. He first came to public notice as the leader of the metalworkers’ strikes
during the later years of the military dictatorship. Out of those strikes would
eventually come the Partido dos Trabalhadores
(Workers’ Party), in which trade unionists were joined by community activists
nurtured by Catholic liberation theology and by leftist academics. Though never
formally a Marxist party, for two decades or more after its foundation in 1979
the PT espoused far-left policies, such as debt default, nationalisatio~
of the banks and wholesale redistribution of wealth. But successive electoraCdefeats persuaded Lula and his key ally in the
party, Jose Dirceu, the PT’s president, to move to the centre
and seek alliances. That process suddenly gathered pace during the 2002
campaign. Weeks before the vote, Lula met Cardoso and signalled
his assent to an IMF loan which committed the next government to stick to
responsible fiscal and monetary policies.46 ‘I changed. Brazil changed,’ Lula
repeated during the campaign. His television commercials, made by a
professional marketing man, projected the soft-focus message of’Lula, peace and love’. It was a return to the pragmatism
of his days as a trade union leader – except that the candidate had donned
Armani suits. That union background marked Lula out from Latin America’s many
more utopian leftists. Jose Sarney, the conservative former president who would
become his ally, was reported to have said of Lula that he was ‘a man who knows
the value of 3 per cent.’ 47 Lula is affable, speaks to ordinary Brazilians in
homespun metaphors, and is by nature a negotiator rather than an ideologue, a
reformist not a revolutionary. ‘Each day, even if we advance a centimetre, we are going forward – without any miracles,
without breaking away from our international commitments, simply doing what
needs to be done,’ he said in 2004.48 But Lula’s own personal history allowed
him to stake a claim to be much more than just an ordinary politician. He was
one of the few leaders who could speak both to the world’s plutocrats at the
World Economic Forum in Davos and to discontented anti-globalisers
at the World Social Forum, which originated in his own party’s stronghold of
Porto Alegre.49
On the night of his
electoral victory, Lula claimed before ecstatic supporters thronging Sao
Paulo’s Avenida Paulista that Brazil had rejected
‘the current economic model, based on dependence, in favour
of a new model of development’. But in practice Lula continued the main thrust
of Cardoso’s economic policies. In the weeks preceding his victory, Brazil’s
financial markets had yet again suffered an attack of nerves: the real lost
around 40 per cent of its value in the six months before the election, falling
to 3.8 to the US dollar.50 That in turn caused prices to rise and sent the
public debt, much of which was denominated in dollars, spiralling
to a peak of 66 per cent of GDP. Lula moved quickly to calm the markets’
nerves. Antonio Palocci, the new finance minister,
was a former Trotskyist turned pragmatist who as mayor of Ribeirao Preto, a
city in Sao Paulo state, had rganized some municipal
services. He immediately announced a tightening of fiscal policy. To head the
Central Bank, Lula named Henrique Meirelles, a former chief executive of
BankBoston who was a member of the PSDB. The Bank nipped inflation in the bud
by yanking up interest rates yet again. The government moved quickly to push a
second pension reform through Congress. Lula’s calculation was plain: a year of
pain followed by three years of gain. He also knew that debt default would be
disastrous for Brazil: most of the public debt was held by Brazilian banks and
pension funds, not foreign investors.
‘It is infantile to
blame the IMF for these measures. We are taking them because they are in
Brazil’s interest,’ Palocci told a packed meeting of
financiers at the Bank of England.51 The government’s economic orthodoxy
brought anguished disillusion to the PT’s left: half a dozen of its
legislators, led by Heloisa Helena, were expelled and set up a far-left
splinter party. But it paid off: the economy grew by 5 per cent in 2004.
Although it slowed again the following year, as the Central Bank kept monetary
policy tight to meet its inflation target, growth picked up again in 2006. The
government was helped by favourable conditions in the
outside world. High world prices for commodities helped Brazil’s exports, while
cheap money in rich countries encouraged investors to seek out the higher
returns offered by emerging markets. By the end of 2006, Brazil’s finances were
in far more robust shape than four years previously. The real had strengthened
to around 2.15 to the dollar (by May 2007 it had reached 1.95). The risk
premium – the spread over the interest rate on American Treasury bonds –
demanded by investors for holding Brazilian bonds fell from some 25 percentage
points to just two. The public debt (net of government assets) fell to 49 per
cent of GDP. The government retired most of the dollar debt, and replaced it
with paper in rea is. In November 2005 it paid off its debt to the IMF early.
Despite the strength of the currency, the export boom meant that Brazil’s
current account moved into surplus in 2003 and stayed there. In late 2005 the
Central Bank began cutting interest rates steadily.
In the 2002 election
campaign, Lula had pledged himself to eliminating hunger. The PT had long rganized Brazil’s social policies as inadequate. Yet once
in government it got off to an oddly unconvincing start. Lula had promised a
scheme called Fame Zero (‘zero hunger’), an old-fashioned and inefficient plan
for food stamps. After a year in which they achieved little beyond setting up a
plethora of overlapping social ministries, Lula’s officials came to rganized the value of a clutch of targeted cash-transfer
schemes for poor families established during the Cardoso government. They
consolidated five of these into Balsa Familia (‘Family Fund’), which they
swiftly expanded. By late 2006, this reached 11 million families, or one in
four. It paid them 95 reais (US$44) a month.52 Bolsa Familia was ‘the most
important incometransfer programme
in the world’, according to Lula.53 His government also increased the real
value of the minimum wage by 25 per cent. ‘How many countries have achieved
what we have: fiscal responsibility and a strong social policy at the same
time? Never in the economic history of Brazil have we had the solid
fundamentals we have now’, he claimed, arguing that the country was now ready
for ‘a leap in quality’.54
In other ways, Lula’s
government was hugely disappointing. That was especially so in its management
of the government bureaucracy (where it placed thousands of party militants in
jobs regardless of qualification), and above all of Congress. The PT had done
less well than Lula in the 2002 election, winning only 91 of the 513 seats in
the lower house of Congress. Lula was less skilful
than Cardoso in building a solid governing coalition. He kept nearly all the
important ministries in the hands of the PT. He could count on the support of a
handful of small left-wing parties. He, or rather Jose Dirceu, his chief of
staff, also struck deals with several rent-a-parties. But in 2005 the
government was rocked by revelations about those deals. After the head of one
of these parties was implicated in a bribery scam at the federal postal
service, he retaliated with claims that the PT was paying a monthly stipend,
dubbed the mensaliio, to dozens of members of
Congress from allied parties in return for their votes. Much of the money was channelled through an advertising man who received many
government contracts, and who was then found to have repaid part of a bank loan
taken out by the PT. The scandal forced the resignations of Dirceu, a dozen
other senior officials and the entire top leadership of the ruling party. What
made it all the more reprehensible was that the PT had long presented itself,
sanctimoniously, as holding a monopoly on political ethics in Brazil. To make
matters worse, Palocci was forced to resign as finance
minister in 2006 over corruption claims stemming from his period as mayor of
Ribeirao Preto.55
Lula insisted that he
knew nothing of the mensaliio. Many Brazilians,
especially poorer ones, appeared either to give him the benefit of the doubt,
or to conclude that his party was no more corrupt than any of the others. Much
of Brazil’s press took a different view, and became implacably hostile to Lula.
The scandal damaged the PT’s standing among the middle class. But economic
stability and Bolsa Familia, together with the affection that many poorer
Brazilians felt for their president, won Lula a second term at an election in
October 2006, in which he secured 61 per cent of the vote in a run-off ballot.
Whereas in 2002, Lula had polled heavily in Brazil’s more developed south and
south-east, this time he owed victory to the votes of the poorer, more backward
north and north-east. Normally governing parties do well in Brazilian
elections, but the scandals cost the PT seats. It only partially replicated
Lula’s gains among the poor in the north-east.56 At the outset of his second
term, Lula rganized an alliance with the centrist,
catch-all PMDB, still one of the largest parties in Brazil but one with a
voracious appetite for patronage and pork.
Overall, progress
outweighed disappointment in Brazil. Much had been achieved over the previous
dozen years. The proportion of the population living in poverty had fallen from
43 per cent in 1993 to 30.7 per cent in 2005. Income distribution was less unequal
than at any time in the previous three decades.57 These achievements were the
result of price stability and democratic social policy, notably universal
primary education and anti-poverty measures. The incomes of the poor rose
steadily, and they bought more: prices of food and medicines fell in 2004 and
2005. That was all the more remarkable since rapid economic growth still proved
elusive. In Lula’s first term, growth averaged just 3.3 per cent a year while
the world economy grew at 4.8 per cent.58 This was partly because of the
continued reliance on high interest rates for price stability, and to
compensate for relatively lax fiscal policy. The government piled up primary
fiscal surpluses, but once debt payments were taken into account, the public finances
were still in overall deficit. The debt burden was gradually falling, but it
remained heavy: interest payments continued to cost the government up to 5 per
cent of GDP.
Critics argued that
the Lula government should have made a far more aggressive effort to reduce the
debt while conditions in the financial markets were benign. Even after the
reforms, the annual deficit in the public-sector pension system still cost taxpayers
the equivalent of 4.5 per cent of GDP. Too much public spending was still
constitutionally mandated, giving the government little room to re-jig it to favour the less well-off. Instead of fixing this and
cutting wasteful spending, of which there was much, the government relied on
higher tax revenues to achieve its primary surpluses. The result was that the
tax burden, all told, amounted to 35 per cent of GDP in 2006 – a higher figure
than in the United States. Since the 1988 constitution, governments issued an
average of 37 different tax rules per day, according to the Brazilian Institute
of Tax Planning.59 Around 40 per cent of employment was still in the informal
economy. So the tax burden on legal businesses was stifling. It was one reason
why investment was still relatively low, at around 16.3 per cent of GDP in
2005. Another reason was that public investment remained derisory. The Cardoso
administration set up arms-length regulatory agencies to attract private
investment to telecoms, roads and electricity. The Lula government mistrusted
these, changed the rules and failed to attract significant investment. The
result was potholed roads, clogged ports and a big deficit in drinking water
and sewerage. These problems were aggravated by institutional failures and
political corruption. After four years in Brazil as the World Bank’s
representative, Vinod Thomas mused: ‘People wonder why, after so many years of
so much investment in roads with external financing, the country is not yet
able to maintain these assets, even though there are large taxes on gasoline to
finance investment.’ 60 Logistics costs in Brazil are twice as high as in
developed countries, he noted.
Much else remained
partly or wholly unreformed. The burden of regulation was as stifling as that
of taxation. Rigid labour laws deter companies from
hiring more workers. The agency charged with policing monopolies and promoting
competition was slow and insufficiently independent. Despite the trade opening
of the 1990S, Brazil remained relatively protectionist. Imports faced an
average tariff of 13 per cent and bureaucratic obstacles. The mensaliio scandal, and the difficulties of constructing
legislative majorities, pointed to the need for political reforms. In the 2006
election, no fewer than 21 parties won seats in the lower house of Congress, a
record. The mounting threats to the security of citizens from rganized crime and everyday violence pointed to the need
for reforms of police, prisons and judiciary.
In his memoirs,
Cardoso writes with feeling that: ‘The struggle to bring greater rationality to
the public finances and to contain inflation is like the myth of Sisyphus: no
sooner has it ended than it starts again.’ 61 Brazil’s economic drama over the
past decade can be summed up simply: the cost of sustained political resistance
to fiscal discipline was punishingly high interest rates that sacrificed
economic growth and private consumption to the fiscal privileges of relatively
better-off groups. Nevertheless, with stability achieved, economic growth was
gradually edging up and Brazil was becoming a less unequal country. Its
combination of stability, relative economic openness and democratic social
reform lacked the dynamism of Chile, but its progress in reducing poverty and
inequality looked far more sustainable than Venezuelan populism. What made
Brazil’s progress all the more remarkable was that it was the fruit of the
patient construction of democratic consensuses.
Mexico: Reform Stalled By Democracy
A couple of kilometres to the north of the Zacalo
in Mexico City lie the ruins of Tlatelolco, TenochtitIan’s
twin city in Aztec times. Tlatelolco was the site of what was at the time the
largest market anywhere in the Americas. It was also the scene of the final act
in the Spanish conquest of the capita1.62 All that is left are the depleted
bases of a dozen or more temple platforms set in a sunken garden. The site is
overlooked by the monastery church of Santiago Tlatelolco, its austere baroque
bulk fashioned by the Spaniards from the reddish black volcanic stone of the
ruined temples. Beyond the church rises the ugly early 1960s concrete tower
that housed the Mexican foreign ministry until 2006, when it moved to a taller
building of glass and steel in the city centre. On
the other three sides stand the apartment blocks of a government housing
project from the same era. The raised open space of concrete flagstones between
the buildings is called the Plaza de las Tres Culturas
or the Square of the Three Cultures – indigenous, Spanish colonial and
republican mestizo. In the ideology of the Institutional Revolutionary Party
(PRI) these fused more harmoniously than in the architectural clashes of the
square. At least so claims the stone plaque overlooking the garden: ‘On August
13th 1521 heroically defended by CuauhtemoE
Tlatelolco fell into the power of Hernan Cortes. It was neither a triumph nor a
defeat. It was the painful birth of the mestizo people that is Mexico today.’
More recently the
square was the site of another act of bloodshed, one that in retrospect would
also come to be seen as marking another painful birth – that of Mexican
democracy. In 1968 the student protests that began in Paris and swept campuses
across the world from Berkeley to Berlin found an echo in Mexico. Students and
their professors took over the National University and the Polytechnic in
Mexico City. Many of the leaders admired Che Guevara, but above all the
movement stood for freedom of political expression.63 The president at the
time, Gustavo Diaz Ordaz, was a narrowminded authoritarian. Even as the student
movement was fizzling out, he saw in it a threat to Mexico’s image in the
world: the Olympic Games were due to open in Mexico City in mid-October. On the
evening of 2 October, a march by a few thousand students was due to end with a
rally in the square at Tlatelolco. As the marchers prepared to listen to
speeches, watched by the army, members of a government-organised
plain-clothes paramilitary squad, acting as agents provocateurs, fired on the
crowd from a balcony in one of the apartment blocks, wounding the army general
in charge. That prompted the army to rake the square with fire from armoured cars, bazookas and machine guns as well as small
arms. The exact death toll is still not known. Contemporary newspaper accounts
talked of up to 28 dead and 80 wounded. The student movement itself put the
figure at 150 civilians and 40 members of the security forces killed. The
Guardian, a British newspaper, claimed that 325 people were killed.64 After the
massacre, the regime’s characteristic response was denial, captured by Rosario
Castellanos, a poet, in lines carved into a second stone monument in the
square, this one unveiled on a rainy evening in October 1993 on the 25th
anniversary of the massacre:
Who? Whom? Nobody. The Next Day, Nobody.
The square awoke
swept clean; the newspapers gave as the main news the state of the weather. And
on the television, on the radio, in the cinema there was no change in the programme, no special announcement, nor a minute of silence
at the banquet (For the banquet indeed continued).65
Nevertheless, the
massacre of Tlatelolco would prove to be a profound shock to the PRI system. It
punctured the official myth of consensual political order. It alienated the
middle class who had been the system's greatest beneficiaries - Octavio Paz,
the poet, was the first to respond, resigning as Mexico's ambassador to India.
It would cause future governments to react in ways that eventually would
further destabilise the system. As Enrique Krauze, a
historian, puts it: 'There had been a profound loss of legitimacy on that dark
night of Tlatelolco ... Though the deep-seated cult of authoritarian government
in Mexico would not recognise the fact, 1968 was both
its highest point of authoritarian power and the real beginning of its
collapse.' 66
In the decades after
the Second World War, Mexico had enjoyed rapid economic growth. This reached
its apogee under the long stewardship of Antonio Ortiz Mena as finance minister
from 1958 to 1970. During that period, private investment was favoured, real wages rose at an annual average rate of 6.4
per cent, the exchange rate was fixed at 12.5 pesos to the dollar, the public
debt was low and the budget in balance. Ortiz Mena called it 'stabilising development'.67 It was jettisoned by Luis
Echeverria, who succeeded Diaz Ordaz as president in 1970. As interior minister
in 1968, Echeverria was complicit in the massacre of Tlatelolco and the
repression of the student movement. As president, he proclaimed a 'democratic
opening' but only within narrow limits: there was a second student massacre in
1971, and the government launched a secretive 'dirty war' against peasant
guerrillas in the Sierra Madre del Sur. At the same time, he appeared to
embrace many of the ideas of the student leaders. He posed as a champion of the
third world, and launched rhetorical attacks on businessmen (whose investment
slowed as a result). He redoubled efforts to co-opt the universities and the
middle class by throwing public money at them. The total number of
public-sector jobs expanded by a staggering amount, from 600,000 in 1970 to 2.2
million in 1976.68 He paid for the breakneck expansion of the state by printing
and borrowing money. Over his term, foreign debt increased sixfold while the
real value of wages halved as inflation took off. Jose Lopez Portillo,
Echeverria's successor, initially seemed to promise more moderate government.
But the discovery of a huge oilfield offshore in the Gulf of Campeche allowed
Lopez Portillo to resume the policies of Echeverria, until falling oil prices
and rising interest rates caused the public' finances to collapse like a house
of cards.
If Tlatelolco had
damaged the PRI's political legitimacy, the devaluation, debt default and bank nationalisation of 1982 undermined its claim to economic
competence. Yet the PRI's retreat from power and the transition to democracy in
Mexico would be extremely gradual and occupy almost two more decades. It had
formally begun with a political reform in 1978, which legalised
the Communist Party and other left-wing groups. The opposition was allowed to
win a quarter of the seats in the Chamber of Deputies the following year.
However, the established order did not lightly surrender power to a divided but
increasingly determined opposition to its right and left. Miguel de la Madrid,
who as president from 1982 to 1988 had to cope with the wreckage left by Lopez
Portillo, was an economic liberal. He began to return the economy to the
policies of Ortiz Mena and 'stabilising development'.
But he did little to reform politics. The government's response to a
devastating earthquake in the centre of Mexico City
in 1985 showed a characteristic mixture of denial and incompetence. Among some
370 buildings that collapsed was one of the blocks of flats at Tlatelolco,
killing 700 people. In all, 20,000 people were killed and another 180,000 were
left homeless. In many cases it was left to unofficial volunteers to rescue
survivors from the rubble and care for the homeless. Out of this tragedy came a
powerful grass roots movement for urban renewal, a novelty in a country where
the state left little room for independent civic organisations.69
De la Madrid eschewed
an opportunity to move towards democracy and fair voting when he failed to
intervene after the National Action Party (PAN), the conservative opposition,
was fraudulently denied an overwhelming victory in an election for governor of the
northern state of Chihuahua in 1986. He also exercised the traditional
presidential prerogative of choosing his successor, Carlos Salinas. That
prompted the most serious split in the PRI for almost half a century.
Cuauhtemoc Cardenas, a former governor of Michoacan and the son of Mexico's
most revered president, had rallied much of the PRI's left wing against de la
Madrid's liberal economic policies. When Salinas was revealed as the PRI's
presidential candidate in 1988, Cardenas opted to run against him for a clutch
of small left-wing parties. The election marked another milestone in the PRI's
steady loss of credibility. Salinas was declared the winner with 50.4 per cent
to 31 per cent for Cardenas, but only after the interior ministry's computers
tallying the count shut down for several hours. Before the plug was pulled on
the computer system, Cardenas had been ahead?O
Massive demonstrations against electoral fraud took place across the country.
Cardenas probably spared Mexico a bloj'dbath when he
urged his supporters to channel their anger into forming a new Party of the
Democratic Revolution (PRD).
Salinas: Perestroika Without Glasnost
Salinas made a
determined attempt to rebuild the PRI system by restoring its lost reputation
for economic competence while updating its mechanisms of political control.
Though his father had been industry minister in the 1960s, Salinas seemed to be
a new kind of PRI politician. He had a doctorate in political economy from
Harvard. Although prematurely bald, he was aged just forty when he became
president. He spoke softly, but with a hint of steel. He liked to describe
himself as a consensus-builder and negotiator?1 But he was ruthless and
hyperactive. He surrounded himself with a clutch of liberal economists with
doctorates from American universities. They were charged with modernising Mexico. The finance minister, Pedro Aspe,
brought inflation down and renegotiated the foreign debt, restoring stability
and a modicum of economic growth after years of debt-induced stagnation.
Salinas boldly challenged several political taboos: he put aside the PRI's
history of anticlericalism by restoring relations with the Vatican, and ordered
an end to six decades ofland reform, instead granting
members of ejidos (communal farms) the right to obtain individual title to
their plots. For these reforms, he secured the support of the PAN. In the most
iconoclastic move of all, he challenged the deep-rooted anti-Americanism of
Mexico's political leadership by opening negotiations for a free-trade
agreement with the United States and Canada.
This whirlwind of
economic modernisation attracted much praise abroad.
But some of the reforms were less liberal (let alone 'neoliberal') than they
seemed. Salinas left intact the state monopolies of oil and electricity,
excluding energy as well as many services from NAFTA. Telmex,
the telecoms company, was transformed from a public monopoly into a private
one. Foreign banks were barred from the bank privatisation.
The president relied on many of the institutions, levers of power and clientelistic networks of Mexico's corporate state. Private
business was especially loyal. At a dinner in 1993 that would become infamous,
Salinas sat down with two dozen of Mexico's richest businessmen, most of them
beneficiaries of privatisations or other favours. He asked for $500 million for the PRI to fight the
1994 election. Most were happy to stump up their alloted
$25 million.n Inflation was reduced partly through tht pacta, an incomes policy negotiated with business and
with Fidel Velazquez, the general secretary of the Confederation of Mexican
Workers (CTM), the main trade union. Under this arrangement, real wages halved
in the decade to 1992. In that year, the CTM held its Congress in Mexico City's
sports arena. It was an event worthy of the Kremlin's gerontocratic heyday. In
front of a giant portrait of Salinas, scores of elderly union leaders sat in
tiers on a podium, their heads protruding like coconuts in a shy. To
well-orchestrated cheers, Velazquez was re-elected for an eighth consecutive
six-year term at the age of 91. No vote was deemed necessary?3 In deference to
Don Fidel, Salinas did not touch the restrictive labour
laws.
Salinas did make a
few gestures towards political modernisation. He set
up a National Human Rights Commission. For the first time, the PRI surrendered
its monopoly of state governorships, PAN victories being accepted in Baja
California and Chihuahua. But in many other cases, Salinas would wait to see
the strength of opposition protests. He sometimes intervened not to recognise an opposition victory but to force the 'winning'
PRI candidate to resign, to be replaced by a presidential appointee. In all, he
removed 17 governors in 14 of Mexico's 31 states?4 Salinas felt obliged to
enact an electoral reform. This created a Federal Electoral Institute (IFE).
Although nominally independent, it was still controlled by the interior
minister, who chaired its general counciF5 The president could count on a
pliant media, dependent on government money. Those he could not co-opt, Salinas
coerced. Early on, he imprisoned the powerful leader of the oil-workers' union,
ostensibly for corruption but in reality for having favoured
Cardenas. The PRD complained that 250 of its activists were killed during
Salinas's term. Officials continued to reject criticisms of the lack of
political reform. 'There isn't a unique model for democracy,' Salinas insisted
in an interview at Los Pinos, the modernist presidential complex in Chapultepec
Park. 'What there is, is the requirement to respect freedoms and to allow
equality of competition - that's what we're working on and that's what we're
committed to.'76 A senior aide was more candid. Referring to the parallel
between the government's economic reforms and the contemporaneous dismantling
of communism in the Soviet Union, he said bluntly: 'The Soviet Union shows that
it is not easy to do perestroika and glasnost at the same time. The worst of
all worlds would be to be left with neither, and without a government or
society that functions.' 77
Salinas also tried to
rebuild the PRI's support among the poor. Migration to the cities and the
growth of the informal economy meant that millions of Mexicans had slipped
through the ruling party's corporatist net of peasant, trade union and profeSSional organisations. To
reach them, Salinas created the National Solidarity Programme
(Pronasol). Over his six-year term, this swallowed
$18 billion, or around 40 per cent of total public investment. It handed out mOlleyfor building health clinics, school classrooms, rural
roads and community development projects. In an attempt to bypass what
officials saw as a sclerotic bureaucracy and cut corruption, the money went
mainly to mayors, backed by newly created Solidarity committees. The programme was closely identified with Salinas himself.
Under its auspices, almost every week he would leave Los Pinos and criss-cross the country. In elaborately choreographed trips
by plane, helicopters and convoys of 4X4S, he would whisk to half a dozen
events in a day, opening drinking-water schemes or health clinics in dusty
villages and handing out property titles in urban shantytowns. Poverty experts criticised the programme for not
reaching the poorest and for its lack of co-ordination - the new clinics might
lack doctors for example. But above all it was designed to be politically
effective. It made Salinas popular and helped the PRI to win comfortably a
mid-term election in 1991.78
In the end Salinas
over-reached himself. Even before the end of his term, his attempt to rebuild
the PRI and its regime began to unravel. Some of his advisers talked of turning
the PRI into the Solidarity Party. Together with his choice of Luis Donaldo Colosio, a gentle and loyal associate, as the presidential
candidate for 1994, this stirred fears that Salinas would seek to remain in
charge, breaking an unwritten rule of the system. Undercurrents of corruption
eddied around the presidential family. All this exploded into the open with
three (still-unresolved) murders. The elderly cardinalarchbishop
of Guadalajara was killed by drug traffickers as he arrived at the city's
airport. Then Colosio himself was shot dead by a lone
gunman at a campaign rally in Tijuana - a political assassination of a gravity
unmatched in Mexico since the murder of Alvaro Obregon by a Catholic fanatic in
1928. Months later, Francisco Ruiz Massieu, the PRI's general secretary and
former husband of Salinas's sister, was the victim of a contract killing in the
centre of Mexico City.
These murders were
not the only violent challenge to political order. On 1 January 1994, the date
that NAFTA came into effect, several hundred Indian guerrillas seized the
colonial town of San Cristobal de las Casas in the southern state of Chiapas in
the name of the previously unknown Zapatista Army of National Liberation
(EZLN). As Carlos Fuentes, the novelist, put it, just when Mexico was moving
closer to North America its rulers were forcibly reminded that parts of their
country still belonged to Central America. Chiapas had never known democracy -
the PRI regularly won elections there with more than 90 per cent of the vote.
Unlike in the rest of Mexico, the state's ranchers and coffee hacendados had successfully resisted land reform, and now
Salinas had ended any chance of it. Militarily, the Zapatista uprising would be
brief. After more than a hundred people were killed as the army drove the
rebels out of San Cristobal and other towns, Salinas quickly declared a
unilateral ceasefire. Far from shoring up authoritarianism as some of its
critics feared, NAFTA constrained the regime's ability to unleash repression
because it focussed the outside world's attention on
Mexico. Initially, at least, the Zapatistas attracted widespread sympathy,
thanks in part to the semiotic skills of their leader, a ski-masked former
university teacher of Marxist philosophy who styled himself Sub-Comandante
Marcos.79 They would gradually be rendered irrelevant, in large part because of
Marcos's inability to adapt to the arrival of democracy.
Days after Ernesto
Zedillo took over as president on 1 December 1994, the cracked edifice of salinismo came tumbling down. The political turmoil of an
electoral year had caused Salinas and Aspe to abandon their previous
macroeconomic prudence. Monetary policy was loosened and the government began
to finance itself with tesobonos (short-term dollar
debt). The political violence gave investors the jitters: money was flying out
of the country. When Zedillo took office on 1 December, outstanding tesobonos were equal to twice the value of the Central
Bank's reserves.80 Once again, as it had at the end of each presidential term
since 1976, political handover coincided with economic turmoil, pointing to the
regime's post-Tlatelolco instability. Three weeks later, after a botched
attempt to widen the exchange-rate band under which the peso had gradually
devalued against the US dollar, Zedillo's government let the currency float.
After weeks of drift, with the help of loans from the United States Treasury
and the IMF, the government managed to stabilise the
economy and recovery quickly followed. But the cost had been heavy. The
exchange rate was stabilised by means of high
interest rates, wage controls, and increases in VAT and in
government-controlled prices. The economy slumped: GDP contracted by 6 per cent
in 1995, but domestic demand fell by 14 per cent and would not recover its
level of 1994 for three years. To make matters worse, many of the newly privatised banks faced collapse. Many of their new owners
were inexperienced; in one or two cases they were corrupt. They lent
recklessly, in some cases to insiders and/or in dollars. Having benefited from
lax regulation under Salinas, they received generous treatment from Zedillo
when they got into difficulties. In essence, they were allowed to pass to the
government their non-performing loans, some of which were to their own
directors. And the government offered unlimited deposit insurance. The Zedillo
administration did belatedly tighten supervision and accounting standards, and
lifted the ban on foreign commercial banks. By 2006 foreign banks accounted for
more than four-fifths of the system. In all, the bank bailout cost the taxpayer
around 20 per cent of GDP.81
The bailout reflected
the government's weakness. It was 'the best deal we could get. We spent years
battling to make the economic numbers add up and to restore confidence',
according to Liebano Saenz, Zedillo's chief of
staff.82
The new president was
an unexciting technocrat, lacking Salinas's political skills. But he had some
important qualities: he was honest and decent, he believed in economic reform
and he was a democrat. 'The time has come for democracy to extend to all areas
of life in our society,' he said in his inaugural address to Congress.83 Right
from the outset, he said that he preferred the rule of law to the unwritten
rules of presidential supremacy, that he would maintain a 'healthy distance'
from the PRI and that he would not choose his successor.84 This amounted to a
voluntary abdication of authoritarianism. He would later partially retreat from
this, but it was far too late for any significant restoration of presidential
power. Zedillo took two other crucial steps towards democracy. Within days of
his taking office, Congress approved a judicial reform that created an
independent and powerful Supreme Court. In 1996, after painstaking negotiation
achieved consensus on the main points among the three main parties, the Federal
Electoral Institute was reformed to become wholly independent of government,
along with its sister organis-!!tion,
the electoral tribunal. The government also pushed through a reform granting
independence to the Central Bank. It took timid steps to loosen the state
monopoly over energy, but beyond a few private companies building power
stations these didn't amount to much in practice.
In February 1995, in
the depths of economic turmoil, Zedillo broke another of the unwritten rules of
the system: he ordered the arrrest of Raul Salinas,
Carlos's elder brother, for the murder of his former brother-in-law, Ruiz
Massieu. The murder investigation degenerated into a gothic farce. But, months
later, the Swiss authorities froze about $130 million they found in secret bank
accounts belonging to Raul, some opened with a false passport. Swiss officials
claimed that some of this money came from the drug trade. There had been
whispers for years that Raul had been enriching himself through embezzlement
and influence-peddling. A federal investigation found that some of the money in
the accounts had been transferred by Carlos Salinas while president.85 In 2005,
Raul Salinas was released from prison on bail after an appeal court quashed his
conviction for murder, but he remained under investigation in Mexico and France
for illicit enrichment.86
Zedillo could restore
Mexico's fortunes but not those of the PRI. If the 1982 debt crisis damaged its
reputation for economic competence, this was destroyed by the 1994-5 debacle.
As most Mexicans saw their living standards plummet, they were angered by the
bailout of the billionaire bankers and by the revelations of corruption at the
top. The PRI itself turned against the economic reforms, which had radically
reduced the scope for political patronage. At a party convention in 1996 to
shouts of 'down with neoliberalism' new rules were approved which required the
party's presidential candidate to have held elected office - a changed aimed at
disqualifying the reforming technocrats. In the mid-term election of 1997, for
the first time the PRI lost its majority in the lower-house of Congress.
Cuauhtemoc Cardenas gained partial retribution for 1988 when he was elected as
the first-ever governor of the Federal District (the inner core of Mexico
City), a post that had hitherto been filled by presidential appointment. In
2000, after 72 years in power, the PRI would finally lose the presidency.
Fox: Gridlocked Democracy
Vicente Fox was
ideally equipped to end the rule of the PRI. A farmer who had been the manager
of Coca-Cola’s Mexican operations, Fox came late to politics. In 1991 he was
denied victory in an election for governor of the central state of Guanajuato
by fraud; he won four years later and almost immediately launched a
presidential campaign. His popularity obliged the PAN, a party of conservative
lawyers, to choose this rough-edged businessman as its candidate. He was
thick-skinned, determined and a natural media performer. His campaign was
simple but devastatingly effective: he promised el
cambia (‘the change’), but not adventurism. He appealed to democrats across the
political spectrum.
On the face of things
Fox’s victory seemed to set the seal on Mexico’s transition from authoritarian
politics and an inward-looking state-dominated economy to an outward-looking, rivatized liberal democracy. But in many ways he turned out
to be a disappointing president, partly because that transition was both more
complicated and less complete than it appeared.87 Fox stoked expectations,
promising more economic reforms and growth of 7 per cent a year, but was unable
to deliver much of either. Just as he moved into Los Pinos, Mexico’s economy
was hit by two blows from outside. In the United States the dotcom bubble
burst, slowing industrial production on both sides of the border. NAFTA had
helped Mexico recover swiftly after 1995, but it had tied the country’s
fortunes ever more closely to those of the United States’ economy. At the same
time, China joined the World Trade Organisation,
marking the arrival of a powerful competitor to Mexico for footloose
manufacturing plants. These twin blows caused three years of economic
stagnation and the loss of some 700,000 jobs, most of them in the maquiladora
(assembly) plants producing goods for export. The private sector responded,
cutting costs. Although some maquiladoras, especially in low-value businesses
such as textiles and toys, moved to China, Mexico continued to attract
investment in higher-value goods, such as cars and electronics. Growth picked
up in the second half of Fox’s term. But the economy continued to be held back
by many vestiges of the corporate state. Labour
productivity remained low, at only about a third of that in the United States.
Despite NAFTA, much of the domestic economy was dominated by monopolies or
oligopolies. Some were state-owned, such as Pemex, the grossly overmanned and
inefficient oil firm. Others were privately owned, such as Telmex,
the dominant telecoms firm. The cost of restricted competition was tangible: on
average, telecoms costs were higher than in China or Brazil as well as in the
United States; in 2006 Mexico had fewer telephones per head than Brazil
although it rivatized eight years earlier.
Electricity costs are disproportionately high too, despite big subsidies to the
state-owned power companies.
NAFTA has tended to
accentuate the gap between the prospering north of the country and the
backward, poorer and more indigenous south. Public policies failed to bridge
the gap. Although Fox promised an ambitious programme
of infrastructure development (mainly roads and electricity) for the south,
called Plan Puebla-Panama, not much happened. The government did nothing to
encourage alternatives to subsistence farming nor to reform education so that
it offered equality of opportunity. In some cases, this was not for want of
trying. Fox sent reforms of energy, taxes and labour
laws to Congress. But the PAN lacked a legislative majority, and the president
lacked the political skills to fashion consensus. There was an underlying
political problem. Unlike in Spain or even in Chile, the end of authoritarian
rule was not accompanied by a concerted effort to fashion new democratic
political institutions. Power has rapidly seeped away from the presidency – to
state governors and mayors, to an independent media and above all to Congress
and the party leaders. In principle, that is both democratic and positive. The
problem is that there are no rules to encourage co-operation among these
different actors.
Yet as he left power
in 2006, Fox could point to some solid achievements. During his presidency
Mexico enjoyed greater political freedom than perhaps at any other time in its
history. He maintained economic stability: inflation dropped to just 3.7 per cent
in 2006; in the second half of his six-year term, growth picked up, averaging
almost 4 per cent a year. A few years of singledigit
inflation transformed the financial markets with surprising speed, as Guillermo
Ortiz, the Central Bank’s governor noted. In 2000, the credit-rating agencies
began to award investment-grade status to Mexican government debt. In 1999, the
maximum term of government bonds was one year, and most were either denominated
in US dollars or linked to inflation. In October 2006, the government was able
to issue a thirty-year peso bond whose yield was not linked to inflation. A
conservative fiscal policy meant that in 2006, the government only absorbed 16
per cent of national savings, down from 80 per cent in 2000. That has helped
everyone else borrow more cheaply. Bigger Mexican companies can now raise money
cheaply with peso bonds of their own. The banks finally started lending again
as interest rates came tumbling down. A re-organised
government housing fund, together with bank mortgages, triggered a
house-building boom. Across Mexico, new housing estates sprouted. A quietly
expanding middle class saw tangible benefits from stability. At the same time,
innovative social policy helped to tackle extreme poverty. The Zedillo
government replaced Salinas’s Solidarity programme
with a less politicised and more effective targeted
anti-poverty scheme called Progresa. This gave a
small monthly stipend to mothers provided they kept their children in school
and took them for regular health checks. Normally each Latin American president
feels the need to re-invent the wheel. But Fox kept Progresa,
changing its name to Oportunidades, and expanded it
so that by 2006 it was reaching 5 million families, or around a quarter of the
total population.
Calderon By A Whisker
The presidential
election of 2006 reflected the fine balance in Mexico between progress and
frustration. The campaign was dominated by Andres Manuel Lopez Obrador, the
candidate of the centre-left PRD. As governor of the
Federal District, he kept himself constantly in the public eye, with new roads,
non-contributory pensions for the elderly and a daily early-morning press
conference at which he set the political agenda. He combined this practical
action with lacerating criticism of Fox and of the rich and powerful in Mexico.
He promised to govern for the poor, and railed against the bankers and
businessmen who he said had benefited from crony capitalism. He slammed the
economic policy of the past two decades as 'a failure' that delivered 'zero per
capita growth' (in fact, per capita income did grow between 1983 and 2005 but
at the unimpressive rate of around 0.5 per cent a year). He said he would
maintain fiscal balance ('you can't have deficits') but implausibly said he
would finance a big increase in public investment merely by cutting
bureaucratic waste.88
For many months, as
Lopez Obrador led the opinion polls, the only question in Mexican political
circles was whether he would be a second Hugo Chavez or a second Lula. In
reality, the answer was neither. He resembled Argentina's Nestor Kirchner in
his profound lack of interest in the world beyond his own country; he took
pride in not having a passport. His political mentor was Echeverria. Lopez
Obrador had spent his formative political years in the PRI, leaving to join
Cardenas in 1988. His detractors saw in L6pez Obrador a throwback to the PRI's
authoritarian populism of the 1970S. In a country where politics was long
dominated by backroom deals, Lopez Obrador was a politician of the public plaza
in the tradition of South America rather than Mexico. He sometimes showed scant
regard for the law, and two of his senior aides were implicated in corruption.
However, when Fox's government tried to remove him from the presidential race
by bringing criminal charges against him in 2005 for a minor violation of planning
law by the city government, the effort rebounded. It was widely seen as
disproportionate, politicised justice and merely
boosted his popularity. But Lopez Obrador made mistakes of his own, such as
insulting Fox and staying away from a first campaign debate. For all his
political skills, he was a polarising figure who
scared middle-of-theroad democrats. Many of them
switched their support to Felipe Calderon, who had beaten Fox's own nomInee to be the candidate of the PAN. Though lacking in
oratorial charisma, Calderon was a solid and well-prepared politician. Fairly
or not, he portrayed Lopez Obrador as a 'danger to Mexico', a second Chavez;
Fox and the country's top businessmen weighed in on his behalf.
When Mexico voted on
2 July, Calderon (PAN) won with 35.9 per cent of the vote against 35.3 per cent
for Lopez Obrador (PRD), a margin of just 233,831 votes out of 42 million. The
PRI's Robert Madrazo, an old-style political boss but an economic pragmatist,
polled a meagre 22.2 per cent. So confident of victory had Lopez Obrador's
campaign been that Manuel Camacho, one of his closest aides, wrote in an
article published the day after the election that the voting had taken place
'in exemplary fashion' and that 'democracy is going to win'.89 Nevertheless,
when the result was adverse, Lopez Obrador immediately cried fraud, though he
never produced any plausible evidence. He demanded a vote-by-vote recount, even
though two counts of the votes had produced a similar result. To get his way,
he launched a campaign of 'civil resistance'. For seven weeks, his followers
camped out in the Zocalo and along Reforma, Mexico City's grandest avenue. The
electoral tribunal ordered a recount of 9 per cent of the ballot boxes - those
in which Lopez Obrador's campaign claimed that most irregularities had
occurred. But this only shaved 10,000 votes from Calderon's margin of
victory.9o Even so, Lopez Obrador refused to concede defeat. 'To hell with your
institutions,' he cried, calling Fox 'a traitor to democracy' and Calderon a
usurper. He proclaimed himself Mexico's legitimate president.
But by then, most
Mexicans had stopped listening to him. His actions in defeat seemed to prove
right the fears of his detractors. His attempt to emulate Bolivia's Evo Morales
and use street protests to topple an elected president failed. His followers did
not make up the mass social movement he claimed. Talking to those camped out in
Reforma, it was clear that many of them were clients of the political machine
he had built while governor of the Federal District. There was much irony and
little truth in his claim that the 2006 election was a repeat of 1988. The
truth was that Mexico's independent electoral authorities passed a severe test
in 2006, with only a few glitches. The irony was that many of Lopez Obrador's
closest aides were, like him, former PRI officials who had been complicit in
the fraudulent campaigns of the past. In the view of Hector Aguilar Camin, a
historian, the protests of 2006 were those that the PRI didn't stage when it
lost power in 2000. 'Alternation in power had happened very cheaply for us.
It's the first protest against this young democracy, done by the ex-priistas of the PRD.' 91 It passed almost unremarked by
Lopez Obrador that the PRD had secured its best-ever result in Mexico's
Congress in the 2006 election. The party's six state governors, and many of its
legislators, began quietly to work through the institutions he disdained,
negotiating legislation with the new government.
The narrowness and
disputed nature of his mandate meant that Calderon faced a difficult task in
governing Mexico, let alone pushing through pending reforms. But he had certain
advantages. Unlike Fox, Calderon was a party man through and through. Aged only
44 in 2006, he had much political experience, having headed the PAN's
congressional caucus. A lawyer, he also had technocratic credentials, having
studied economics and, at Harvard, public administration. He faced a more favourable economic situation than Fox had inherited
(although once again a new government in Mexico took office with the US economy
decelerating). Such was Mexico's financial strength that the peso and stockmarket sailed through the election and its aftermath
without blinking. Even without further reform, Mexico's economy could grow at a
steady 4 per cent or so over the next few years, according to Francisco Gil,
Fox's finance minister.92 He drew a parallel with Spain, which like Mexico
opened up its economy and cast off authoritarian rule. Like Mexico, Spain
suffers from weak productivity but has achieved sustained economic growth by
combining manufacturing exports to a large and rich neighbour
(the European Union, in its case) with dynamic construction and tourism
industries and a strong banking system. Spain, however, had stronger
institutions and a more educated population than Mexico when it embarked on
democracy. And Mexico needs to grow faster than Spain if it is to achieve a
rapid reduction in poverty. Such is the lack of opportunity that each year
during Fox's government some 500,000 Mexicans risked the increasingly hazardous
border crossing to migrate to the United States. The task facing Calderon was
to create a more dynamic economy by demolishing the remaining vestiges of the
corporate state and to help to fashion more effective democratic institutions.
In the quarter of a
century since the 1982 debt crisis, and especially in the past dozen years,
Mexico has changed radically. It is a much more democratic, pluralist and open
society than it was under Salinas, let alone under Lopez Portillo. Yet the economic
reforms remained partial, and their success was only partial too.
1. Visits
in 2005
2. Interview
with Nicolas Eyzaguirre, finance minister, Santiago, 2005.
3.
Bosworth, Barry P, Dornbusch, Rudiger and Laban, Raul (eds) (1994), The Chilean
Economy: Policy Lessons and Challenges, The Brookings Institution, Washington
DC, p. 23.
4. Dornbusch,
Rudiger and Edwards, Sebastian, 'Exchange Rate Policy and Trade Strategy', in
ibid., p. 81.
5. Solimano, Andres, 'The Chilean Economy in the
1990S: On a "Golden Age" and Beyond', in Taylor, Lance (ed.) (1999),
After Neoliberalism: What Next for Latin America?, University of Michigan
Press, p. 115.
6.
Interview
7.
Lagos, Ricardo (2003), Conversaciones en el Camino, Ediciones
B, Santiago, PP, 48-9.
8.
Speech to the Third Ministerial Conference of the Community of Democracies,
Santiago, April 2005, reproduced in Lagos, Ricardo (2005), The 21st Century: A
View from the South, First, London, p.55.
9. Interview
with Vittorio Corbo, Central Bank president, Santiago, January 2005.
10. Financial
Times, 6 May 2006.
11. Angell,
Alan, 'Democratic Governability in Chile', unpublished paper supplied to the
author.
12. Solimano,
'The Chilean Economy in the 1990s, p. 123; SalmonChile
(undated), La Acuicultura en
Chile, TechnoPress SA, Santiago, Chapter 1.
13.
Interview
14. World
Economic Forum, press release, 28 September 2005, Geneva.
15. According
to Ricardo Lagos, interview with the author, Santiago, January 2005.
16. Ibid.
17.
Interview
18. 'Chile:
Testing times for Michelle Bachelet', The Economist, 24 June 2006.
19. Speech
to the Community of Democracies in Lagos, The 21st Century, P.54.
20. See
Sola, Lourdes and Whitehead, Laurence (2006), Statecrafting
Monetary Authority: Democracy and Financial Order in Brazil, Centre for
Brazilian Studies, University of Oxford, Introduction pp. 1-11.
21. Cardoso,
Fernando Henrique (2006), A Arte da Politica: A Hist6ria que Vivi, Civilizayao
Brasileira, Rio de Janeiro, p. 140.
22. The
term was coined by Guillermo O'Donnell. See Chapter 11, p. 283.
23. Weyland,
Kirk, 'The Brazilian State in the New Democracy', in Kingstone, Peter R and
Power, Timothy J (eds) (2000), Democratic Brazil: Actors, Institutions and
Processes, University of Pittsburgh Press, p. 40.
24. Cardoso,
A Arte da Politica, p. 108.
25. Lamounier,
Da Independencia aLula,
P.258.
26. Power,
Timothy, 'Political Institutions in Democratic Brazil: Politics as a Permanent
Constitutional Convention', in Kingstone/Power, Democratic Brazil, p. 21.
27. Much
of the political science literature on Brazil published in the second half of
the 1990S was deeply pessimistic even as the country's prospects were being
transformed. That was because it was based on fieldwork conducted during the
1980s or early 1990s.
28.
Cardoso/Winter, The Accidental President, pp. 175-7.
29.
Ibid., p. 180.
30.
Cardoso, A Arte da Politica, p. 141.
31.
Ibid., p. 208.
32.
World Bank (2006e), p. 140.
33.
Cardoso/Winter, The Accidental President, p. 167; Cardoso, A Arte da Politica, Pp,130-5.
34.
Lamounier, Da Independencia aLula,
p. 205.
35.
Ibid., p. 213.
36.
'Brazil: Inactive Workers, Inactive Congress', The Economist, 27 June 1997;
'Reforming Brazil: Is it for Real', The Economist, 17 May 1997.
37.
Study by IPEA, a government-backed think-tank, cited in Cardoso, Eliana,
'Brazil's Currency Crisis: The Shift from an Exchange Rate Anchor to a Flexible
Regime', in Wise/Roett, Exchange Rate Politics in Latin America, p.72.
38.
ECLAC/CEPAL, Panorama Social de America Latina, 2005, P.130. Some of this
increase was gobbled up by pensions.
39.
Interview
40.
Cardoso, Eliana, Brazil's Currency Crisis, P.76.
41.
Cardoso, A Arte da Politica, PP.388 and 415.
42.
Cardoso, Eliana, Brazil's Currency Crisis, Pp.70 and 82.
43.
Cardoso, A Arte da Politica, PP.363-6.
44.
'Brazil 2015: A Reform Agenda', presentation by Armando Castelar Pinheiro, IDB,
Washington DC, 4 October 2005.
45.
Cardoso, A Arte da Politica, pp. 12-13.
46.
'Brazil's Presidential Election: The Meaning of Lula', The Economist, 3 October
2002.
47.
This anecdote was told to the author by Julio Maria Sanguinetti, a former
president of Uruguay.
48.
'Poor Man's Burden', Barry Bearak, New York Times
Magazine, 27 June 2004.
49.
Having governed it for the best part of two decades, in 2004 the PT lost an
election for mayor of Porto Alegre to Jose Foga<;:a, a PMDB member and
supporter of Cardoso.
50.
'Brazil's Presidential Election: From Pauper to President', The Economist, 31
January 2002.
51.
Meeting attended by the author, London, September 2003.
52.
'Brazil: Love Lula if You're Poor, Worry if You're Not', The Economist, 30
September 2006.
53.
The Economist, 24 February 2006.
54.
Ibid.
55.
Palocci resigned after an aide admitted leaking
details of the bank account of the caretaker at a house in Brasilia rented by
several of the minister's former associates from Ribeiriio
Preto. The leak was an attempt to smear the caretaker, who had contradicted the
minister's testimony to a Congressional committee that he had not visited the
house. See 'Corruption in Brazil: House Calls', The Economist, 23 March 2006.
56.
See Hunter, Wendy and Power, Timothy J (forthcoming), 'Rewarding Lula:
Executive Power, Social Policy, and. the Brazilian Elections of 2006', Latin
American Politics and Society.
57.
Data from Instituto de Pesquisa Economica Aplicada (IPEA), available at www. ipeadata.gov.br
58.
In March 2007 Brazil's statistics institute issued a new set of national
accounts that measure the contribution of services to GDP more accurately.
Under the old methodology, annual average growth during Lula's first term was
2.6 per cent, only slightly higher than in the Cardosa period. Where possible,
this part uses the new GDP figures.
59.
World Bank (2006e), p.74.
60.
Cardoso, A Arte da Politica, p. 168.
61.
Thomas, Hugh (1993), The Conquest of Mexico, Pimlico, pp. 296-8.
62.
Krauze, Mexico: Biography of Power, p. 697.
63.
Poniatowska, Elena (1992), La noche de Tlatelolco, Ediciones Era, Mexico City, P·llO.
64. The
poem was written especially for a book of interviews with survivors prepared by
Elena Poniatowska, a young journalist who would later become one of Mexico's
best-known writers, and which when it was published in 1971 made the first dent
in the regime's wall of silence concerning the massacre. Poniatowska, La noche de Tlatelolco, p. 163.
65.
Krauze, Mexico: Biography of Power, pp.736-7.
66.Ibid., p. 681. 67,
Ibid., p.743.
67.
Preston, Julia and Dillon, Samuel (2005), Opening Mexico: The Making of a
Democracy, Farrar, Strauss and Giroux, Chapter 4; Aguilar Camin, Hector (2004),
Despues del milagro, 16th
edition, Ediciones Cal y Arena, Mexico City, Chapter
1.
68.
Preston/Dillon, Opening Mexico, Chapter 6. In 1994, Arturo Nunez, the head of
the IFE, admitted that the computer system had been forced to fail. See
Dominguez, Jorge I and McCann, James A (1996), Democratizing Mexico: Public
Opinion and Electoral Choices, Johns Hopkins University Press, PP.151-2.
69.
Interview.
70.
Preston/Dillon, Opening Mexico, p. 481.
71.
Congress covered by author. See 'Mexico: Ring In the Old', The Economist,
14March 1993.
72.
Preston/Dillon, Opening Mexico, p. 219.
73.
Gomez Tagle, Silvia, 'Public Institutions and Electoral Transparency', p. 89,
in Middlebrook, Kevin J (2004), Dilemmas of Political Change in Mexico,
Institute of Latin American Studies, London, and Center for US-Mexican Studies,
San Diego.
75.
Interview with the author, Mexico City, July 1991.
76.
Interview with the author, Mexico City, July 1991.
77.
'Mexico: Salt of the Earth', The Economist, 19 October 1991.
78.
'The Clash in Mexico' and 'Mexico: The Revolution Continues', The Economist, 22
-January 1994.
79.
PrestonlDillon, Opening Mexico, pp. 245-50.
80.
Haber, Stephen, 'Why Institutions Matter: Banking and Economic Growth in
Mexico', paper available at www.stanford.edu/-haber/papers; World Bank (2001),
P·242.
81.
Interview with the author, Mexico City, September 2006.
82.
Preston/Dillon, Opening Mexico, p. 261.
83.
Rubio, Luis and Kaufman Purcell, Susan (1998), Mexico Under Zedillo, Lynne Rienner, Boulder, Colorado, p. 14.
84.
PrestonlDillon, Opening Mexico, P.305.
85.
Financial Times, 15 June 2005; El Pais, 26 June 2005. Raul Salinas claimed iri an interview with the Financial Times in 2005 that the
money was an 'investment fund' that he was managing for a group of Mexican
businessmen, but he gave no explanation as to why it was held in private Swiss
accounts.
86.
The following paragraphs draw on Reid, 'Time to Wake Up'.
87.
Press conference attended by the author, Mexico City, May 2005; 'Mexico: Will
the Real Andres Manuel Lopez Obrador Please Stand Up?', The Economist, 28 May
2006.
88.
'Triunfo ciudadano', Manuel Camacho Solis, El
Universal, Mexico City, 3 July 2006.
89.
The tribunal criticised Fox and the businessmen for
their campaign interventions, though it is hard to imagine these would have
provoked comment in many other countries.
90.
Interview
91.
Interview
For updates
click homepage here