Europe
faces a banking crisis it has not wanted to admit even exists.
Among the factors responsible for the European banking crisis has been
the persistent unwillingness of bankers and regulators to acknowledge they had
a problem. Because of the politicized nature of European banking, European
governments often require their banks to have a smaller cash cushion than banks
elsewhere in the world. For example, when the European Banking Authority ran
stress tests in July to prove the banks’ stability, the banks were only
required to demonstrate a capital adequacy ratio (the percentage of assets held
in cash to cover operations and losses) of 5 percent, half the international
standard. Even with such lax standards, eight European banks still failed the
tests. Since banks need cash to engage in the business of making loans, there
is very strong resistance among European banks to valuing their assets at
market values. Any write-downs force them to redirect their free cash from
making loans to covering losses. The lower capital requirements of Europe mean
that their margin for error is always very thin.
Increasing that margin requires more cash reserves, a process known as
recapitalization. Recapitalization can be done any number of ways, but most of
the normal options are currently off the table for European banks. The
preferred method is to issue more good loans so that profits from new business
can eat away at the losses from the bad. But in a recessionary environment, new
high-quality loans are hard to find. Banks also can raise money by issuing
stock or selling assets. However, few in Europe, much less elsewhere, want to
increase their exposure to the European banking sector, largely because of
banks’ gross exposure to Europe’s sovereign debt crisis. European banks in
particular, which are in the best position to know, are reluctant to become
more entangled in each other’s affairs and often shy away from lending to one
another, even for terms as short as overnight.
Even in good times, any serious recapitalization efforts would flood the
market with stock shares and assets for sale. These are not good times.
Remember that banks are the primary purchasers of European sovereign debt and
Europe is already in a sovereign debt crisis. Adding more assets for banks to
buy would create the near-perfect buyer’s market: rock-bottom prices. There are
indeed some would-be purchasers, Sweden from within the European Union and
Turkey and Russia from without, but their combined interest adds up to merely
billions of euros, when hundreds of billions are needed.
Which brings us to the sheer size of the problem. The Europeans are
leaning toward a new regulation that would force all European banks to have a
capital adequacy ratio of 9 percent, hoping that such a change would decisively
end speculation that Europe’s banks face problems. It will not.
According to the European Banking Authority, the institution that is
responsible for carrying out stress tests, two-thirds of Europe’s banks are
currently below the 9 percent threshold, and that assumes no past or future
reduction in the value of sovereign bonds for any European governments, no new
sovereign bailouts that damage investor confidence or asset values, no mortgage
crisis, no new bank collapses in Europe akin to that of Franco-Belgian bank Dexia and no renewed recession. Simply increasing capital
adequacy ratios to 9 percent will cost about 200 billion euros (about $270
billion). The regulation also assumes that all European banks have been
scrupulously honest in their reporting; Dexia, for
example, shuffled assets between its trading and banking books to generate a
misleading capital adequacy ratio of 12 percent, when the reality was in the
vicinity of 6 percent. Forcing the banks to have a thicker cushion is certainly
a step in the right direction, but the volume is insufficient to resolve any of
the problems outlined to this point, and the latest rumor out of Europe’s
pre-summit negotiations is that perhaps only 80 billion euros is actually
needed.
If the banks cannot recapitalize themselves, the only remaining options
are state-driven recapitalization efforts. Here, again, current circumstances
hobble possible actions. The European sovereign debt crisis means many
governments are already facing great stresses in meeting normal financing
needs, doubly so for Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Italy, Belgium and Spain. No
eurozone states have the ability to quickly come up with several hundred
billion euros in additional funds. Keep in mind that, unlike the United States,
where the Federal Reserve plays a central role in bank regulation and
remediation, the European Central Bank has no role whatsoever. The individual
central banks of the various eurozone states lack the control over monetary
policy to build the sort of highly liquid support mechanisms required to
sequester and rehabilitate damaged banks. Such central bank actions remain in
the arsenal of the non-eurozone states, the United Kingdom, for one, has been
using such monetary policy tools for three years now. However, for the eurozone
states, the only way to recapitalize is to come up with cash, and as Europe’s
financial crises deepen, that’s becoming ever harder to do.
There is one other option that the eurozone states do have: the European
Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), better known as the European bailout fund,
which manages the Greek, Irish and Portuguese bailouts. With its recent
amendments, the EFSF can now legally assist European banks as well as European
governments. But even this mechanism faces three complications.
First, the EFSF has yet to bail out a bank, so it is unclear what
process would be followed. The French have indicated they would like to tap the
facility to recapitalize their banks because they see it as being politically
attractive (and not using just their money). The Germans have indicated that
should a bank tap the facility then the sovereign that regulates the bank must
commit to economic reforms; the EFSF, therefore, should be a last resort. Not
only is there not yet a process for EFSF bank bailouts, but there also is not
yet an agreement on who should hold the process. Even if the Germans get their
way on the EFSF, remediation and supervisory structures must first be built.
Second, the EFSF is a very new institution with only a handful of staff.
Even if there were full eurozone agreement on the process, the EFSF is months
away from being able to implement policy. And if the EFSF is going to have the
ability to restructure banks, that power is, for now, directly in opposition to
EU treaties that guarantee all banking authority to the member-state level.
Finally, the EFSF is fairly small in terms of funding capacity. Its
total fundraising ceiling is only 440 billion euros, 268 billion of which it
has already committed to the bailouts of Greece, Ireland and Portugal over the
course of the next three years. Unless the facility is significantly expanded,
it simply will not have enough money to serve as a credible bank-financing
tool. To handle all of the challenges the Europeans are hoping the EFSF will be
able to resolve, yet it is estimated the facility will need its capacity
expanded to 2 trillion euros. Finding ways to solve that problem
likely will dominate the European summits being held during the next few days.
Basically France wants to have the European Central Bank at the centre of any effort to increase the firepower of the
bailout facility, the EFSF. Germany does not. Germany instead wants bondholders
to face much steeper "haircuts" on Greek debt. France does not - in
part because of what it might mean for some politically important French banks.
Sovereign Debt: The Expected
Problem
A meeting of eurozone ministers today (Oct. 21) is largely dedicated to
the topic, as is the Oct.
23 summit of EU heads of government. Yet European governments continue to consider
the banking sector largely only within the context of the ongoing sovereign
debt crisis.
This is exemplified in Europeans’ handling of the Greek situation. The
primary reason Greece has not defaulted on its nearly 400-billion euro
sovereign debt is that the rest of the eurozone is not forcing Greece to fully
implement its agreed-upon austerity measures. Withholding bailout funds as
punishment would trigger an immediate default and a cascade of disastrous
effects across Europe. Loudly condemning Greek inaction while still slipping
Athens bailout checks keeps that aspect of Europe’s crisis in a holding
pattern. In the European mind, especially the Northern European mind, a handful
of small countries that made poor decisions are responsible for the European
debt crisis, and while the ensuing crisis may spread to the banks as a
consequence, the banks themselves would be fine if only the sovereigns could
get their acts together.
This is an incorrect assumption. If anything, Europe’s banks are as
damaged as the governments that regulate them.
When evaluating a problem of such magnitude, one might as well begin
with the problem as the Europeans see it, namely, that their banks’ biggest
problem is rooted in their sovereign debt exposure.
The state-bank contagion problem is fairly straightforward within
national borders. As a rule the largest purchaser of the debt of any particular
European government will be banks located in the particular country. If a
government goes bankrupt or is forced to partially default on its debt, its
failure will trigger the failure of most of its banks. Greece does indeed
provide a useful example. Until Greece joined the European Union in 1981,
state-controlled institutions dominated its banking sector. These institutions’
primary reason for being was to support government financing, regardless of
whether there was a political or economic rationale justifying that financing.
The Greeks, however, have no monopoly on the practice of leaning on the banking
sector to support state spending. In fact, this practice is the norm across
Europe.
Spain’s regional banks, the cajas, have become
infamous for serving as slush funds for regional governments, regardless of the
government in question’s political affiliation. Were the cajas
assets held to U.S. standards of what qualifies as a good or bad loan, half the
cajas would be closed immediately and another third
would be placed in receivership. Italian banks hold half of Italy’s 1.9
trillion euros in outstanding state debt. And lest anyone attempt to lay all
the blame on Southern Europe, French and Belgian municipalities as well as the
Belgian national government regularly used the aforementioned Dexia in a somewhat similar manner.
Yet much debt remains for outsiders to own, so when states crack, the
damage will not be held internally. Half or more of the debt of Greece,
Ireland, Portugal, Italy and Belgium is in foreign hands, but like everything
else in Europe the exposure is not balanced evenly, and this time, it is
Northern Europe, not Southern Europe, that is exposed. French banks are more
exposed than any other national sector, holding an amount equivalent to 8.5
percent of French gross domestic product (GDP) in the debt of the most
financially distressed states (Greece, Ireland, Portugal, Italy, Belgium and
Spain). Belgium comes in second with an exposure of roughly 5.5 percent of GDP,
although that number excludes the roughly 45 percent of GDP Belgium’s banks
hold in Belgian state debt.
When Europeans speak of the need to recapitalize their banks, creating
firebreaks between cross-border sovereign debt exposure dominates their
thoughts, which explains why the Europeans belatedly have seized upon the IMF’s
original 200 billion-euro figure. The Europeans are hoping that if they can
strike a series of deals that restructure a percentage of the debt owed by the
Continent’s most financially strapped states, they will be able to halt the
sovereign debt crisis in its tracks.
This plan is flawed. The figure, 200 billion euros, will not cover
reasonable restructurings. The 50 percent writedowns
or “haircuts” for Greece under discussion as part of a revised Greek bailout,
likely to be announced at the end of the upcoming Oct. 23 EU summit, would
absorb more than half of that 200 billion euros. A mere 8 percent haircut on
Italian debt would absorb the remainder.
Moreover, Europe’s banking problems stretch far beyond sovereign debt.
Before one can understand just how deep those problems go, we must examine the
role European banks play in European society.
The Centrality of European
Banking
For example, several differences between the European and American banking
sectors exist. By far the most critical difference is that European banks are
much more central to the functioning of European economies than American banks
are to the U.S. economy. The reason is rooted in the geography of capital.
Maritime transport is cheaper than land transport by at least an order
of magnitude once the costs of constructing road and rail infrastructure is
factored in. Therefore, maritime economies will always have surplus capital
compared to their land transport-based equivalents. Managing such excess
capital requires banks, and so nearly all of the world’s banking centers form
at points on navigable rivers where capital richness is at its most extreme.
For example, New York is where the Hudson meets the Atlantic Octen, Chicago is at the southernmost extremity of the
Great Lakes network, Geneva is near the head of navigation of the Rhone, and
Vienna is located where the Danube breaks through the Alps-Carpathian gap.
Unity differentiates the U.S. and European banking system. The American
maritime network comprises the interconnected rivers of the Greater Mississippi
Basin linked into the Intracoastal Waterway, which allows for easy transport
from the U.S.-Mexico border on the Gulf of Mexico all the way to the Chesapeake
Bay. Europe’s maritime network is neither interlinked nor evenly shared.
Northern Europe is blessed with a dozen easily navigable rivers, but none of
the major rivers interconnect; each river, and thus each nation, has its own
financial capital. The Danube, Europe’s longest river, drains in the opposite
direction but cuts through mountains twice in doing so. Some European states
have multiple navigable rivers: France and Germany each have three major ones.
Arid and rugged Spain and Greece, in contrast, have none.
The unity of the American transport system means that all of its banks
are interlinked, and so there is a need for a single regulatory structure. The
disunity of European geography generates not only competing nationalities but
also competing banking systems.
Moreover, Americans are used to far-flung and impersonal capital funding
their activities (such as a bank in New York funding a project in Nebraska)
because of the network’s large and singular nature. Not so in Europe. There,
regional competition has enshrined banks as tools of state planning. French
capital is used for French projects and other sources of capital are viewed
with suspicion. Consequently, Americans only use bank loans to fund 31 percent
of total private credit, with bond issuances (18 percent) and stock markets (51
percent) making up the balance. In the eurozone roughly 80 percent of private
credit is bank-sourced. And instead of the United States’ single central bank,
single bank guarantor and fiscal authority, Europe has dozens. Banking regulation
has been expressly omitted from all European treaties to this point, instead
remaining a national prerogative.
As a starting point, therefore, it must be understood that European
banks are more central to the functioning of the European system than American
banks are to the American system. And any problems that might erupt in the
world of European banks will face a far more complicated restitution effort
cluttered with overlapping, conflicting authorities colored by national biases.
Demographic Limitations
European banks also face less long-term growth. The largest piece of
consumer spending in any economy is done by people in their 20s and 30s. This
cohort is going to college, raising children and buying houses and cars. Yet
people in their 20s and 30s are the weakest in terms of earning potential. High
consumption plus low earning leads invariably to borrowing, and borrowing is
banks’ mainstay. In the 1990s and 2000s much of Europe enjoyed a bulge in its
population structure in precisely this young demographic, particularly in
Southern European states, generating a great deal of economic activity, and
from it a great deal of business for Europe’s banks.
But now, this demographic has grown up. Their earning potential has
increased, while their big surge of demand is largely over, sharply curtailing
their need for borrowing. In Spain and Greece, the younger end of population
bulge is now 30; in Italy and France it is now 35; in Austria, Germany and the
Netherlands it is 40; and in Belgium it is 45. Consumer borrowing in general
and mortgage activity in particular probably have peaked. The small sizes of
the replacement generations suggests there will be no recoveries within the
next few decades. (Children born today will not hit their prime consumptive age
for another 20 to 30 years.) With the total value of new consumer loans likely
to stagnate (and more likely, decline) moving forward, if anything there are
now too many European banks competing for a shrinking pool of consumer loans.
Europe is thus not likely to be able to grow out of any banking problems it
experiences. The one potential exception is in Central Europe, w here the
population bulges are on average 15 years younger than in Western Europe. The
younger edge of the Polish bulge, for example, is only 25. In time, these
states may be able to grow out of their problems. Either way, the most
lucrative years for Western European banking are over.
Too Much Credit
Germany has extremely high capital accumulation and extremely competent
economic management. One of the many results of this pairing is extremely
inexpensive capital costs. When Germans, governments, corporations or
individuals, borrow money, it is accepted as a near-fact that they will pay
back what they owe, on time and in full. Reflecting the high supply and low
risk, German borrowing rates for governments and corporations have long been in
the low to mid single digits.
The further you move from Germany the less this pattern holds. Capital
availability shrivels, management falters and the attitude toward contract law
(or at least as defined by the Germans) becomes far less respectful. As such,
Europe’s peripheral economies, most notably its smaller peripheral economies,
have normally faced higher borrowing costs. Mortgage rates in Ireland stood
near 20 percent less than a generation ago. Government borrowing rates in
Greece have in the past topped 30 percent.
With that sort of difference, it is not difficult to see why many
European states have striven for inclusion in first, the European Union, and
second, the eurozone. Each step of the European integration process has brought
them closer in financial terms to the ultra-low credit costs of Germany. The
closer the German association, the greater the implicit belief that German
financial resources would help them in a crisis (despite the fact that EU
treaties explicitly rejected this).
The dawn of the eurozone era prompted lenders and investors to take this
association to an extreme. Association with Germany shifted from lower lending
rates to identical lending rates. The Greek government could borrow at rates
that only Germany could demand in the past. Irish borrowers were able to
qualify for 130 percent mortgages at 4 percent. Compounding matters, the
collapse of borrowing costs and the explosion of loan activity occurred at the
same time as Southern Europe’s demographic-driven consumption boom. It was the
perfect storm for explosive banking growth, and it laid the groundwork for a
financial collapse of unprecedented proportions.
Drastic increases in government debt are the most publicly visible
outcome, but it is far from the only one. The least visible outcome is that
extraordinarily cheap credit to consumers triggers an explosion in demand that
local businesses cannot hope to fill. The result is unprecedented trade
deficits as money borrowed from foreigners is used to purchase foreign goods.
Cyprus, Greece, Portugal, Bulgaria, Romania, Lithuania, Estonia and Spain, all
states whose cheap labor when compared to the Western European core should
encourage them to be massive exporters, instead have run chronic trade deficits
in excess of 7 percent of GDP. Most routinely broke 10 percent. Such
developments do not directly harm the banks, but as credit costs return to more
rational levels, and in the ongoing debt crisis borrowing costs for most of the
younger EU members have tripled and more, consumption is coming to a halt. In
the few European markets that demographically may be able to generate
consumption-based growth in the years ahead, credit is drying up.
Foreign Currency Risk
Much of this lending into weaker locations was carried out in foreign
currencies. For the three states that successfully made the early sprint into
the eurozone, Estonia, Slovenia and Slovakia, this was a nonfactor. For those
that did not make the early leap into the eurozone it was a wonderful way to
get something for nothing. Their association with the European Union resulted
in the steady strengthening of their currencies. Since 2004, the Polish, Czech,
Romanian and Hungarian currencies gained roughly one-third versus the euro,
driving down the monthly payments on any euro-denominated loan. That inverted,
however, in the 2008 financial crisis. Then, every regional currency but the
Czech koruna (and Bulgarian lev, which is pegged to the euro) gave back their
gains. For Central Europeans who had taken out loans when their currencies were
at their highs, payments ballooned. More than 10 percent of Polish and
Hungarian mortgages are now delinquent, largely because of currency movements.
New Banking ‘Empires’
The cheap credit of the eurozone’s first decade allowed several
peripheral European states a rare opportunity to expand their network of
influence, even if they were not in the eurozone themselves. They could borrow
money from core European banking centers like Germany, France, Switzerland and
the Netherlands and pass that money on to previously credit-starved markets. In
most cases, such credit was offered without the full cost-increase that these
states’ poorer and smaller statures would have justified. After all, these
would-be financial centers had to undercut the more established European
financial centers if they were to gain meaningful market share. This pushed far
more credit into Central Europe than the region otherwise would have attracted,
speeding up the development process at the cost of poor underwriting and a
proliferation of questionable lending practices. The most enthusiastic crafters
of new banking empires have been Sweden, Austria, Spain and Greece.
- Sweden has the happiest record of any of the states that engaged in such
expansionary lending. Being one of the richest countries in Europe and yet not
being a member of the eurozone, Sweden did not experience a credit expansion
nearly as much as other states, instead it served as a conduit for that credit,
augmented by its own, to its former imperial territories. Alone among the
forgers of new banking empires, Sweden’s superior financial stability has
allowed it (so far) to continue financial activities in its target markets,
Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania and Denmark, despite the ongoing financial crisis.
But instead of lending, Swedish banks are now purchasing regional banks
outright. Swedish command of the Danish banking sector, for example, has
increased by 80 percent since the crisis. Through its new local subsidiaries, Swedish
banks now lend more in per capita terms to Danes than they do to their own
citizens, and there is no longer a domestic Estonian banking sector, it is 97
percent Swedish-owned. Such expansionary activity is likely to continue so long
as Sweden can sustain it, as there is a geopolitical angle to Sweden’s effort:
It is seeking to deepen its regional influence not only for economic purposes,
but also to mitigate the rising role of its longtime competitor, Russia.
- Austria has tapped not only eurozone credit but also taken advantage
of favorable carry trades to serve as a conduit for Swiss franc credit into
Central Europe. Just as Sweden is using foreign capital to re-create its
historic sphere of influence in the Baltic, Austria is doing the same in the
lands of the former Austro-Hungarian Empire. Now, the majority of all mortgages
in Poland, Hungary, Croatia and Romania, and a sizable minority in Austria, are
denominated in foreign currencies, courtesy of Austrian banking activity. With
the Swiss franc now locked in at record highs, many of these mortgages are not
serviceable. The Hungarian government has felt forced to abrogate the terms of
many of these loans, knowing that the Austrian banks are now so overexposed to
Central Europe that they have no choice but to take the losses. As the
financial crisis has continued apace, Austria has found itself with more
exposure, fewer domestic resources and greater vulnerability to external forces
than Sweden. So instead of being able to take advantage of regional weakness,
it is finding itself losing market share both at home and in its would-be
financial empire to Russia.
- Spain’s banking empire isn’t even in Europe. Spanish firms
BBVA-Compass and Santander have used the cheap euro credit to massively expand
credit to Latin America. And Spain’s expansion took a somewhat novel route: The
combination of cheap lending at home and in Latin America encouraged more than
a million Latin American Spanish speakers to relocate to Spain and gain
citizenship. To smooth the naturalization process, Madrid mandated that the new
Spaniards be granted top-notch credit, a factor that only added to an already
hyperactive construction sector. Spanish banks’ nearly 500 billion-euro
exposure to Latin America is, for now, holding; only time will tell its impact
to Spain’s bottom line.
The Greek government used its access to cheap credit to build up debt
levels that are now the subject of much discussion across Europe. But much less
is made of its banks, who encouraged consumers both at home and across the
southern Balkans to increase their own debt levels. Being the least experienced
of the four would-be financial centers, Greek banks offered the steepest credit
breaks to the countries with the weakest repayment potential. Like Spain,
Greece also did not make EU membership a condition for lending; vast volumes
accordingly were fed into Macedonia, Serbia and even Albania.
Housing Bubbles
Large volumes of suddenly cheap credit made available to eager consumers
obviously generated a series of sizable housing bubbles.
Spain’s tapping of European credit markets also underwrote the largest
housing boom in Europe. More construction projects have been completed in Spain
in recent years than in Germany, France, Italy and the United Kingdom combined.
The construction sector, both commercial and residential, has now collapsed and
there are about 1 million homes now sitting vacant in a country with just 16.5
million families. Outstanding loans to various real estate interests total some
400 billion euros, all backed by collateral that has lost 20 percent of its
value since the housing market peaked.
In relative terms, Ireland actually did more than Spain. At its peak,
nearly 10 percent of Irish gross national product was dependent upon
construction, with 70 percent of that purely from residences. Half of the
mortgages extended during the Irish real estate boom were made at the peak of
the market between 2006 and 2008. That sector remains in the midst of a fairly
rapid collapse. Residential home prices have reduced by half since their peak
in 2007 and are showing few signs of stabilizing. The Irish government hopes
that with their eurozone bailout package, their banking sector will become
functional again by 2020. Until then, Ireland in effect has no banking sector
and has been financially sequestered from the rest of the eurozone.
Two other European states, the United Kingdom and Sweden, have both
experienced massive increases in home price growth, and both suffered from
price corrections due to the 2008 financial crisis. But prices in both markets
have recovered smartly, with Sweden even bouncing back above its pre-crisis
highs. Sweden, in fact, is still experiencing a massive housing boom, with
annual mortgage credit still expanding at a 30 percent annualized rate.
For updates click homepage
here