Most people will know
from the news by now that the net effect of the 'credit crunch' is
that a reduced pool of capital is being hoarded. That is driving up the cost
for any type of borrowing, with many of the more speculative projects or
borrowers simply being unable to attract money at all. Credit crunches almost
invariably trigger recessions (assuming recessions are not in effect already)
because they greatly degrade the ability of firms, individuals and governments
alike to engage in economic activity.
In time, this will
work through the system, as in the many recessions of the past. For some time,
credit will be extended only to obviously profitable ventures and to deeply
qualified borrowers, while questionable firms are crunched out of business. As
efficiency improves, lenders will become more willing to extend credit to
less-than-sure things. And a recovery will be under way.
Between now and then,
governments will do what they can to lessen the impact of the credit crunch.
Some will enact bailouts, or even nationalizations, of banks to ensure there is
as little of a crunch as possible. Others, think the United States, are looking
to simply take the questionable subprime assets out of the equation altogether
so that the reasons for the credit crunch disappear. Ultimately, mitigating the
effects of a credit crunch comes down to how much a government is able to
tinker with finances; fighting off a credit crunch ultimately requires money,
and not a small amount of it.
That means that there
are three leading criteria to consider. First, there is the degree to which the
government already dominates the economy. Governments tend to not be for-profit
institutions, so issues of creditworthiness or low demand do not, as a rule,
force them out of business. That means that any slowdown hits the private
sector disproportionately, and the more resources the government absorbs, the
fewer resources the private sector has to cope (in comparison, the government
sector tends to just glide on). This factor is far more important in developed
countries, where the state is strong and present throughout society, than in
developing countries, where often broad swathes of territory, even economic
sectors, are beyond the government’s reach.
Second, there is the
level that the state’s budget is already in the red. A key means of
kick-starting growth, and certainly a key means of extending credit, is to
spend money. In theory, government spending can generate demand, create
employment opportunities and help the private sector through a slowdown until
such time that the private sector can take over. (And, of course, government
spending can also be used to bail out banks.) But if the government’s budget is
already in deficit, there is much less roo to
maneuver. A credit crunch means that the cost of borrowing goes up for
everyone, governments included.
Third, there is the
issue of pre-existing national debts. This one is pretty straightforward. If a
country has a history of running fast and loose with its budget, it will have
accrued a hefty national debt. This both increases the costs of future financing
and acts as a drag on existing expenditures because the government has to
factor interest payments into its budget, reducing the amount of resources
available for anything else, such as dealing with a credit crunch.
The map indicates
which states have the capacity to deal with a broad credit crunch based on the
three criteria above.
Of course, the
ability of a state to fight off a credit crunch is only half of the equation.
The remainder involves the severity with which the state is affected. Just as
not all countries are created equal, not all countries will be affected by
financial crises in the same way. For example, the United States can count on
many investors piling into U.S. government debt even on the worst of days. So
financial crises may feel painful, but in reality they require few large-scale
adjustments (bear in mind that in the impossible scenario that every cent of
the $700 billion bailout is somehow lost, that “only” amounts to 5 percent of
the gross domestic product).
But for states
dependent upon foreign investment that also lack the ability to define global
economic trends, Greece comes to mind, the next few months look very bleak
indeed. In contrast, some states that are rich in capital and not particularly
dependent upon foreign capital, nearly all of the Arab oil exporters make this
list, will not suffer from a crisis because they are net exporters of capital
already, and in fact will see phenomenal opportunities unveiled as other states
struggle.
Meanwhile in the USA,
it will take the Treasury Department weeks to hire and train a sufficient cadre
of bureaucrats to run the bailout. The Treasury will not be paying full value
for these assets, so time must be allotted for identification, offers and negotiation
over price. (The Treasury will eventually sell these assets, buying low and
selling high, and so is likely to make a profit for the taxpayer in the long
run. Part of the deals struck are likely to grant the Treasury shares in the
banks. That will increase again the chances of the Treasury earning a profit,
it will choose when and under what market circumstances it sells the shares,
but adding this layer of complexity will also lengthen the negotiations.) And
even a nation as powerful as the United States cannot raise $700 billion in
funding overnight, that will require months, at the very least.
The danger now is
that, between today and the point in the future when the Treasury removes the
mortgage-backed assets from the credit equation, a broader credit crunch will
worsen economic activity which in turn will eat into banks’ profits via more
traditional means. Normally, in a recession, peoples’ incomes suffer and
normal, even healthy, loans fall into default. There are two ends to every
loan: for a borrower, a loan is a way to purchase something; for a lender, it
is a means of making money. Failed loans therefore enervate banks’ health in
precisely the same way that the subprime crisis has. If this
recession-triggered degradation proceeds faster than the Treasury can clear
away the mortgage-backed securities, then the credit crunch will persist, widespread
bank failures may well become inevitable and a “normal” recession could become
something more serious. The Treasury is now in a race against time.
But while the United
States suffers under a time constraint, it has a national plan already in
motion to attack the problem at its source. But while the process in progress
could mark the beginning of the end of the crisis for the United States, the
American credit crunch is only the beginning of the story for the world’s other
two major economic pillars: Europe and Japan.
For updates
click homepage here