By Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
The End Of China’s Economic Miracle
Another subject we
have covered in depth is that among others Beijing’s inward turn will hamper
its ability to build formal legal channels for international labor flows to
respond to China’s rising needs. But pressing domestic demands will lead social
pressures to evolve in darker, underground directions. Examples might include
an expansion of human trafficking of Pakistani and Burmese women into China’s
poor rural areas or the emergence of programs nominally bringing international
students from less developed countries to China for education while exploiting
them as a source of low-cost labor.
What also has
unfolded, for months-long stretches, in hardening frontlines with very high
human costs. Such a reality does not preclude the possibility of significant
new operations by either side and consequent shifts in momentum. Well over a
year into the war, advances will likely come at a much higher price. Ground
that has been fought over, as the generals learned in World War I, is more difficult to move across.
The implications of
China’s institutional pathologies are profound. A future conflict between the
United States and China is not inevitable. But a war could ensue if one or both
sides miscalculate the costs and benefits of
fighting.
As 2022 ended,
hopes were rising that China’s economy—and, consequently, the global
economy—was poised for a surge. After three years of stringent restrictions on
movement, mandatory mass testing, and interminable lockdowns, the Chinese
government had suddenly decided to abandon its “zero COVID” policy, which
had suppressed demand, hampered manufacturing, roiled supply lines, and
produced the most significant slowdown that the country’s economy had seen
since pro-market reforms began in the late 1970s. In the weeks following the
policy change, global oil, copper, and other commodities prices rose on
expectations that Chinese demand would surge. In March, Chinese Premier Li Keqiang
announced a target for real GDP growth of around five percent, and
many external analysts predicted it would go far higher.
Initially, some parts
of China’s economy did indeed grow: pent-up demand for domestic tourism,
hospitality, and retail services made solid contributions to the recovery.
Exports grew in the first few months of 2023, and even the beleaguered
residential real estate market had bottomed out. But by the end of the second
quarter, the latest GDP data told a very different story: overall
growth was weak and seemingly set on a downward trend. Wary foreign investors
and cash-strapped local governments in China did not capitalize on the initial
momentum.
This reversal was
more significant than a typical overly optimistic forecast missing the mark.
The seriousness of the problem is indicated by the decline of China’s durable
goods consumption and private-sector investment rates to a fraction of their
earlier levels and by the country’s surging household savings rate. Those
trends reflect people’s long-term economic decisions in the aggregate, and they
strongly suggest that in China, people and companies are increasingly fearful
of losing access to their assets and are prioritizing short-term liquidity over
investment. That these indicators have not returned to pre-COVID, normal
levels—let alone boomed after reopening as they did in the United States and
elsewhere—is a sign of deep problems.
What has become clear
is that the first quarter of 2020, which saw the onset of COVID, was a
point of no return for Chinese economic behavior, which began shifting in 2015,
when the state extended its control: since then, household savings as a share
of GDP have risen by an enormous 50 percent and are staying at that
high level. Private-sector consumption of durable goods is down by around a
third versus early 2015, continuing to decline since reopening rather than
reflecting pent-up demand. Private investment is even weaker, down by a
historic two-thirds since the first quarter of 2015, including a decrease of 25
percent since the pandemic started. And both these key forms of private-sector
investment continue trending further downward.
Financial markets,
and probably even the Chinese government itself, have overlooked the severity
of these weaknesses, which will likely drag down growth for several years. Call
it a case of “economic long COVID.” Like a patient suffering from that
chronic condition, China’s economic body has not regained its vitality. It
remains sluggish even now that the acute phase—three years of exceedingly
strict and costly zero-COVID lockdown measures—has ended. The
condition is systemic, and the only reliable cure—credibly assuring ordinary
Chinese people and companies that there are limits on the government’s
intrusion into economic life—cannot be delivered.
China’s development
of economic long COVID should be recognized for what it is: the
result of President Xi Jinping’s extreme response to the pandemic, which has
spurred a dynamic that beset other authoritarian countries but that China
previously avoided in the post–Mao Zedong era. Economic development in
authoritarian regimes tends to follow a predictable pattern: a period of growth
as the government allows politically compliant businesses to thrive, fed by
public largess. But once the regime has secured support, it begins intervening
in the economy increasingly arbitrarily. Eventually, in the face of uncertainty
and fear, households and small businesses start to prefer cash savings to
illiquid investments; as a result, growth persistently declines.
Since Deng Xiaoping
began the “reform and opening” of China’s economy in the late 1970s, the
leadership of the Chinese Communist Party deliberately resisted the impulse to
interfere in the private sector for far longer than most authoritarian regimes
have. But under Xi, and especially since the pandemic began,
the CCP has reverted toward the authoritarian mean. In China’s case,
the virus is not the leading cause of the country’s economic long COVID:
the chief culprit is the general public’s immune response to extreme
intervention, which has produced a less dynamic economy. This downward cycle
presents U.S. policymakers with an opportunity to reset the economic leg of
Washington’s China strategy and to adopt a more effective and less self-harming
approach than those pursued by the Trump administration and—so far—the Biden
administration.
No Politics, No Problems, No More
Before the pandemic,
the vast majority of Chinese households and smaller private businesses relied
on an implicit “no politics, no problem” bargain in place since the early
1980s: the CCP ultimately controlled property rights, but as long as
people stayed out of politics, the party would stay out of their economic life.
This modus vivendi is found in many autocratic regimes that wish to keep their
citizens satisfied and productive, and it worked beautifully for China over the
past four decades.
When Xi took office
in 2013, he embarked on an aggressive anticorruption campaign, which along the
way, just happened to take out some of his main rivals, such as the former
Politburo member Bo Xilai. The measures were popular with most citizens; after
all, who would not approve of punishing corrupt officials? And they did not
violate the economic compact because they targeted only some of the party’s
members, who comprise less than seven percent of the population. Xi went
further a few years later by bringing the country’s tech giants to heel. In
November 2020, party leaders made an example of Jack Ma, a tech tycoon who had
publicly criticized state regulators by forcibly delaying the initial public
offering of one of his companies, the Ant Group, and driving him out of public
life. Western investors reacted with concern, but this time, too, most Chinese
were either pleased or indifferent. How the state treated the property of a few
oligarchs was of little relevance to their everyday economic lives.
The government’s
response to the pandemic was another matter entirely. It made visible and
tangible the CCP’s arbitrary power over everyone’s commercial activities,
including those of the smallest players. With a few hours’ warning, a
neighborhood or entire city could be shut down indefinitely, retail businesses
closed with no recourse, residents trapped in housing blocks, and their lives
and livelihoods put on hold.
All major economies
went through some version of a lockdown early in the pandemic, but none
experienced anything nearly as abrupt, severe, and unrelenting as China’s
anti-pandemic measures. Zero COVID was as unsparing as it was
arbitrary in its local application, which appeared to follow only the whims of
party officials. The Chinese writer Murong Xuecun likened the experience to a mass imprisonment
campaign. At times, shortages of groceries, prescription medicines, and
critical medical care beset even wealthy and connected communities in Beijing
and Shanghai. All the while, economic activity fell precipitously. At Foxconn,
one of China’s most important manufacturers of tech exports, workers and
executives publicly complained that their company might be cut from global
supply chains.
What remains today is
widespread fear not seen since the days of Mao—fear of losing one’s property or
livelihood, whether temporarily or forever, without warning and appeal. Some
expatriates tell this story, which is in keeping with the economic data.
Zero COVID was a response to extraordinary circumstances, and many
Chinese believe Xi’s assertion that it saved more lives than the West’s
approach would have. Yet the memories of how relentlessly local officials
implemented the strategy remain fresh and undiluted.
Some say
the CCP’s decision to abandon zero COVID in late 2022 following
a wave of public protest indicated at least some basic if belated, regard for
popular opinion. The about-face was a “victory” for the protesters, in the
words of The New York Times. Yet the same could not be said for ordinary
Chinese people, at least in their economic lives. A month before the sudden end
of zero COVID, senior party officials told the domestic public to expect a
gradual rollback of pandemic restrictions; what followed a few weeks later was
an abrupt and total reversal. The sudden U-turn only reinforced the sense among
Chinese people that their jobs, businesses, and everyday routines remain at the
mercy of the party and its whims.
Of course, many other
factors were in the immense, complex Chinese economy throughout this period.
Business failures and delinquent loans resulted from a real estate bubble that
burst in August 2021 and remains a persistent drag on growth and continues to
limit local government funding. Fears of overregulation or worse among owners
of technology companies also persist. U.S. trade and technology restrictions on
China have done some damage, as have China’s retaliatory responses. Well before
the onset of COVID, Xi had started to boost the role of state-owned
enterprises and had increased party oversight of the economy. But the party had
also pursued some pro-growth policies, including bailouts, investment in the
high-tech sector, and easy credit availability. The COVID response,
however, made clear that the CCP was the ultimate decision-maker
about people’s ability to earn a living or access their assets—and that it
would make decisions seemingly arbitrarily as the party leadership’s priorities
shifted.
Same Old Story
After defying temptation
for decades, China’s political economy under Xi has finally succumbed to a
familiar pattern among autocratic regimes. They tend to start on a “no
politics, no problem” compact that promises business as usual for those who
keep their heads down. But by their second or, more commonly, third term in
office, rulers increasingly disregard commercial concerns and pursue
interventionist policies whenever it suits their short-term goals. They make
examples of a few political rivals and large multinational businesses. Over
time, the threat of state control in day-to-day commerce extends across wider
and wider swaths of the population. Over varying periods, Hugo Chávez and
Nicolás Maduro in Venezuela, Recep Tayyip Erdogan in Turkey, Viktor Orban in
Hungary, and Vladimir Putin in Russia have all turned down this well-worn road.
The economic
ramifications are pervasive when an entrenched autocratic regime violates the
“no politics, no problem” deal. Faced with uncertainty beyond their control,
people try to self-insure. They hold on to their cash; they invest and spend
less than they used to, especially on illiquid assets such as automobiles,
small business equipment and facilities, and real estate. Their heightened risk
aversion and greater precautionary savings drag on growth, somewhat like what
happens in the aftermath of a financial crisis.
Meanwhile, the
government’s ability to steer and protect the economy from macroeconomic shocks
diminishes. Since people know that a given policy could be enforced arbitrarily,
that it might be expanded one day and reversed the next, they become less
responsive to stimulus plans and the like. This, too, is a familiar pattern. In
Turkey, for instance, Erdogan has recently pressured the central bank into
cutting interest rates, which he hoped would fuel an investment boom; what he
fueled instead was soaring inflation. In Hungary, a large fiscal and monetary
stimulus package failed to soften the pandemic’s economic impact, despite the
success of similar measures in neighboring countries.
People walking outside the Shanghai Railway Station,
Shanghai, December 2022
The same trend is
already visible in China because Xi drove up the Chinese private sector’s
immune response to government intervention. Stimulus packages introduced since
the end of the zero-COVID policy, meant to boost consumer spending on cars
and other durable goods, have not gained much traction. And in the first half
of this year, the share of Chinese companies applying for bank loans remained
about as weak as it was back in 2021—at half their
pre-COVID average—despite efforts by the central bank and finance ministry
to encourage borrowing at low rates. Low appetite for illiquid investment and
low responsiveness to supportive macroeconomic policies: that, in a nutshell,
is economic long COVID.
Once an autocratic
regime has lost the confidence of the average household and business, it isn't
easy to win back. A return to good economic performance alone is insufficient,
as it does not obviate the risk of future interruptions or expropriations. The
autocrat’s Achilles’ heel is an inherent lack of credible self-restraint. To
seriously commit to such restraint would be to admit to the potential for
abuses of power. Such commitment problems are precisely why more democratic
countries enact constitutions, and their legislatures oversee budgets.
Deliberately or not,
the CCP has gone farther in the opposite direction. In March, China’s
parliament, the National People’s Congress, amended its legislative procedures
to make passing emergency legislation easier, not harder,. Such legislation now
requires the approval of only the Congress’s Standing Committee, which
comprises a minority of senior party loyalists. Many outside observers have
overlooked the significance of this change. But its practical effects on
economic policy will not go unnoticed among households and businesses, who will
be left still more exposed to the party’s edicts.
The upshot is that
economic long COVID is more than a momentary drag on growth. It will
likely plague the Chinese economy for years. More optimistic forecasts have not
yet factored in this lasting change. To the extent that Western forecasters and
international organizations have cast doubt on China’s growth prospects for
this year or the next, they have fixated on easily observable problems such as
chief executives’ fears about the private high-tech sector and financial
fragility in the real estate market. These sector-specific stories are
important, but they matter far less to medium-term growth than the economic
long COVID afflicting consumers and small businesses, even if that
syndrome is less visible to foreign investors and observers. (It may be
apparent to some Chinese analysts, but they cannot point it out publicly). And
although targeted policies may reverse problems limited to a particular sector,
the broader syndrome will persist.
In recent months,
Bank of America, the Economist Intelligence Unit, and Goldman Sachs, for
example, have each adjusted downward their forecasts for Chinese GDP growth
in 2023, shaving off at least 0.4 percentage points. But because the
persistence of economic long COVID has not yet sunk in, and because
many forecasts assume, erroneously, that Beijing’s stimulus programs will be
effective, China watchers still overestimate prospects for growth in the next
year and beyond. Forecasts of annual GDP growth in 2024 by the
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (5.1 percent) and the
International Monetary Fund (a more modest 4.5 percent) could be off by 0.5
percent or more. The need to correct downward will only grow over time.
China’s private
sector will save more, invest less, and take fewer risks than before the
economic long COVID, let alone before Xi’s second term. Durable goods
consumption and private-sector investment will be less responsive to stimulus
policies. The likely consequences will be a more volatile economy (because
macroeconomic policy will be less effective in inducing households and smaller
businesses to offset downturns) and more public debt (because it will take more
fiscal stimulus to achieve the desired impact). These, in turn, will drive down
average economic growth over time by reducing productivity growth, in addition
to lowering private
investment in the near term.
Yet Xi and other CCP leaders
may take this as vindication of their belief that the country’s economic future
lies less with the private sector than with state-owned enterprises. Even
before the pandemic, government pressure was leading banks and investment funds
to favor state-owned enterprises in their lending, while investment in the
private sector was in retreat. Research by the economist Nicholas Lardy has
found that the share of annual investment going to China’s private-sector firms
peaked in 2015 and that the state-owned share has risen markedly since then,
year-over-year. Economic long COVID will reinforce this trend for two
reasons. First, private investors and small businesses will be cautious and
remain liquid rather than make large loan-financed bets. Second, any tax cuts
or stimulus programs aimed at the private sector will deliver less immediate
bang for the buck than investment in the state sector. Add to this Xi’s ongoing
push for self-sufficiency in advanced technology, which is subjecting a growing
share of investment decisions to even more arbitrary party control, and the
outlook for productivity growth and returns on capital only dims.
Open-Door Policy
Some U.S. and allied officials,
seeing Chinese solid growth as a threat, might take heart from the country’s
current ailment. But a slower-growing and less stable Chinese economy will also
have downsides for the rest of the world, including the United States. Suppose
the Chinese keep saving rather than investing and continue to spend more on
domestically delivered services than on tech and other durable goods that
require imports. In that case, their overall trade surplus with the rest of the
world will keep growing—any Trump-style efforts to curtail it notwithstanding.
And when another global recession hits, China’s growth will not help revive
demand abroad as it did last time. Western officials should adjust their
expectations downward but not celebrate too much.
Neither should they
expect economic long COVID to weaken Xi’s hold on power shortly. As
Erdogan, Putin, and even Maduro can attest, autocrats who break the “no
politics, no problem” compact tend to remain in office despite slowing,
sometimes even cratering, growth. The perverse reality is that local party
bosses and officials can often extract more loyalty from a suffering populace,
at least for a while. In an unstable economic environment, the rewards of being
on their good side—and the dangers of drawing their ire—go up, and safe
alternatives to seeking state patronage or employment are fewer. Xi might take
economic measures to paper over the cracks for some time, as Orban and Putin
have done successfully, using EU funds and energy revenues. With
targeted government spending and sector-specific measures, such as
public-housing subsidies and public assurances that the government’s crackdown
on tech firms is over, Xi might still temporarily boost growth.
But those dynamics
will not last forever. As many observers have rightly pointed out, youth
unemployment in China is troublingly high, especially among higher-educated
workers. If CCP policies diminish people’s long-term economic
opportunities and stability, discontent with the party will grow. Among those
means, some are already self-insuring. In the face of insecurity, they are
moving savings abroad, offshoring business production and investment, and even
emigrating to less uncertain markets. Over time, such exits will look more and
more appealing to wider slices of Chinese society.
Even if outflows of
Chinese financial assets remain limited for now, the long-term incentives are
clear: for average Chinese savers, who hold most, perhaps even all, their life
savings in yuan-denominated assets, buying assets abroad made sense even before
the pandemic. It makes even more sense now that prospects for growth at home
are diminishing, and the risks from CCP caprices are rising.
The United States
should welcome those savings, along with Chinese businesses, investors,
students, and workers who leave searching for greener pastures. But current
policies, enacted by both the Trump and the Biden administrations, do the
opposite. They seek to close off American universities and companies to Chinese
students and workers. They restrict inward foreign investment and capital
inflows and discourage Chinese companies from moving into the U.S. and allied
economies for production, research, and development. They reduce downward
pressure on the yuan and diminish, in the eyes of ordinary Chinese people, the
contrast between their government’s conduct and that of the United States.
These policies should be reversed.
Easing these
restrictions need not involve reducing trade barriers. However much this might
benefit U.S. economic and foreign policy on its terms. If the American economy
did a better job of attracting productive Chinese capital, labor, and
innovation, those inflows would partly compensate for the substantial economic
costs incurred due to the U.S. trade conflict with China. Neither would Washington
need to water down national security restrictions on critical technologies. To
prevent illicit technology transfers by Chinese investors, the United States
and its allies should restrict access to some specific sectors, just as they
restrict certain sensitive exports. In truth, however, most Chinese
intellectual property theft from U.S. companies takes the form of cybercrime,
reverse engineering, and old-fashioned industrial espionage—for the most part,
it needs to be addressed directly by means other than restricting inward
foreign investment.
Removing most
barriers to Chinese talent and capital would not undermine U.S. prosperity or
national security. It would, however, make it harder for Beijing to maintain a
growing economy that is simultaneously stable, self-reliant, and under tight
party control. Compared with the United States’ current economic strategy
toward China, which is more confrontational, restrictive, and punitive, the new
approach would lower the risk of a dangerous escalation between Washington and
Beijing, and it would prove less divisive among U.S. allies and developing
economies. This approach would require communicating that Chinese people,
savings, technology, and brands are welcome in the United States, the opposite
of containment efforts that overtly exclude them.
Several other economies,
including Australia, Canada, Mexico, Singapore, the United Kingdom, and
Vietnam, already benefit from Chinese students, businesses, and capital
inflows. In so doing, they are improving their economic strength and weakening
the CCP’s hold at home. That effect would be maximized if the United
States followed suit. If Washington goes its way instead—perhaps because the
next U.S. administration opts for continued confrontation or greater economic
isolationism—it should at the very least allow other countries to provide
off-ramps for Chinese people and commerce rather than pressuring them to adopt
the containment barriers that the United States is installing. Regarding
Chinese private commerce, the United States should think of suction, not
sanctions, especially as the CCP exercises firmer control of Chinese
businesses.
The more Beijing
tries to stave off outflows of useful factors of economic production—for
instance, by maintaining strict capital controls and limiting listings of
companies in the United States—the more it will deepen the sense of insecurity
driving those outflows in the first place. Other autocrats have tried this
self-defeating strategy; many were forced to keep temporary capital controls in
place indefinitely to move people and companies to make more efforts to get
around them. As seen repeatedly in Latin America and elsewhere, including
during the final decline of the Soviet Union, such policies almost invariably
spur more outflows of people and capital.
The Chinese economy’s
affliction with economic long COVID presents an opportunity for U.S.
policymakers to change strategy. Instead of trying to contain China’s growth at
great cost to their economy, American leaders can let Xi do their work for them
and position their country as a better alternative and a welcoming destination
for Chinese economic assets. Even knowledgeable officials overlook how well
this strategy served the United States in facing systemic rivals in the
twentieth century. It is often forgotten that it was far from evident during
the Great Depression that the U.S. economy could outperform fascist regimes in
Europe, and similar uncertainty about relative growth performance recurred
throughout much of the Cold War. Despite that uncertainty, the United States
emerged victorious partly because it maintained an open door for people and
capital, siphoning off talent and investment and, ultimately, turning
autocratic regimes’ economic controls against them. As
the CCP struggles with its self-afflicted economic long COVID,
that strategy is worth reviving today.
For updates click hompage here