By Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
Deglobalization
A consensus is
emerging that the world is cleaving into blocs—not only geopolitically but economically,
too. In 2020, the economist Douglas Irwin wrote that “the COVID-19 pandemic is
driving the world economy to retreat from global economic integration.” In the
years since, how to manage this purported deglobalization has been a consistent
theme at World Economic Forum meetings; in May, an Economist cover
depicted a map of the world physically fracturing into competing economic
blocs. The associated story presumed that deglobalization is a long-term
certainty, arguing that it is becoming “visible in the economic data, as
investors reprice assets and redirect capital in a less integrated world.” Last
week, a Bloomberg columnist piled on, concluding that “global trade and finance
are fragmenting into rival and increasingly hostile blocs, one centered on
China and extending into the global South and another around the United States
and other Western countries.”
But there is a
problem with the assumption that deglobalization is a fact on the ground: the
data does not fully back it up. As evidence of continuing deglobalization,
observers often cite phenomena such as the United States’ reluctance to
establish new free-trade deals, the debilitation of the dispute-settlement
system overseen by the World Trade Organization (WTO),
the proliferation of new national measures restricting trade, and declines in
both short- and long-term capital flows from their past peaks. The COVID-19
pandemic certainly did reveal that economic interdependence carries risks, and
the efforts Russia has made since 2022 to use its natural gas pipelines to
influence the G-7’s response to its invasion of Ukraine—as well as the many
sanctions the G-7 has imposed to try to weaken Russia’s economy—have
highlighted the vulnerabilities that can arise when countries trade across
geopolitical divides. But a closer look at economic data shows that even though
governments have increasingly adopted policies aimed at strengthening their own
resilience, the world economy is still evolving to become more, not less,
globalized in key ways—and more dependent on Chinese supply in particular.
Global trade surged
during the pandemic, and the world’s trade with China accelerated rather than
slowed. A pandemic-era shift toward goods and away from services partly
accounts for the acceleration. But the growth in trade with China also reflects
the fact that China is simply producing things—high-tech exports such as
electric vehicles, wind turbines, solar panels, and vital electronic and
battery components—at a price point few can match. Between 2019 and 2023,
China’s manufacturing surplus rose by about a percentage point of global GDP;
it is now far larger than the surpluses run by Germany and Japan, the world’s
other manufacturing powerhouses.
There is also less to
the fall in capital flows than meets the eye. The decline in foreign direct
investment (FDI) after 2016, for example, largely resulted from specific
changes in tax regulations that led to a big reduction in the use of
special-purpose vehicles in Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and a few other key
European tax centers. And that tax simplification has not blunted one of the
less savory forms of globalization: trade and financial flows that appear to
serve only as a vehicle for multinational tax avoidance.
The now pervasive
misperception of the world’s economy has consequences. Policymakers’ efforts to
defend globalization by equating more global trade flows with increased
efficiency tend to ignore the ways reality is more complex: for example, even
those pursuing a healthy form of globalization will need to work to reduce
multinational corporations’ tax avoidance. More fundamentally, if observers
downplay the extent to which the world’s economies are still integrated, they
will underestimate the cost of actions that would fracture the world economy,
such as launching a conflict over Taiwan or a unilateral U.S. retreat from
trade. World leaders must take steps to increase their economies’ resilience,
but they must first understand those steps’ true costs.
Trading Up
The idea that the
world’s economy is deglobalizing took hold after the 2016 election of U.S.
President Donald Trump. In his rhetoric, Trump repudiated the post–World War II
bipartisan consensus around the value of free trade. He also made some genuine
policy shifts: pulling out of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP),
renegotiating the North American Free Trade Agreement to tighten the rules of
origin for the trade of automobiles, and introducing tariffs on roughly
three-fifths of the trade between the United States and China.
A container ship leaving the port of Santos, Brazil,
May 2024
But globalization has
deep roots now, and such bilateral trade policies did little to change its
fundamental trajectory. New trade deals and tariff programs always get a lot of
ink. In reality, the changes in tariff rates in modern free-trade deals tend to
be small, as most tariffs are already low or zero. Countries lacking
preferential access to the U.S. market can still do incredibly well with the
WTO’s standard trade terms. U.S. imports from Southeast Asia have soared in the
past half-dozen years. The Southeast Asian members of the TPP increased their
exports to the United States much more rapidly after Trump withdrew from the
TPP than they had been able to before.
Any serious
discussion of what drives trade must extend beyond tariffs and trade deals. The
value of currencies also factors into trade flows, as do worldwide patterns of
saving and investment. The dollar has remained strong since the United States
withdrew from the TPP, and American consumers have not hesitated to buy foreign
goods, helping drive the growth in U.S. imports.
Chinese exports to
the United States are down since the 2018 introduction of the Trump tariffs, as
are China’s reported holdings of U.S. Treasury and government-backed agency
bonds. But those indicators are poor measures of these two economies’ true interconnection.
When considering the impact of the United States’ much-ballyhooed bilateral
tariffs on Chinese products, it is important to look beyond U.S. data showing a
fall in direct imports from China and pay more attention to data
from China itself. Surprisingly, those data reveal a much smaller decline in
direct trade with the United States and a steep rise in Chinese exports to
countries that are now exporting more to the United States. Careful studies of
the impact of the Trump tariffs by the Bank of International Settlements and
the economist Caroline Freund have found that the most important effect of
bilateral tariffs was to lengthen supply chains, not to shrink overall global
trade or to reduce the United States’ fundamental reliance on Chinese-sourced
critical inputs. More Chinese parts now head to Malaysia, Thailand, and
Vietnam—and to a more modest degree, Mexico—for final assembly. The underlying
dependence on China is less visible, but no less substantial.
In fact, since the introduction
of the Trump tariffs, China’s economy has become only more central to world
trade. The data points here are often overlooked by American and European
commentators, but they are unambiguous. Over the five years between the end of
2018 and the end of 2023, China’s exports of manufactured goods increased by 40
percent, from $2.5 trillion to $3.5 trillion, much more than the roughly 15
percent increase between 2013 and 2018.
Although China’s
ratio of exports to GDP fell in the years following the global financial
crisis, exports have once again become a crucial driver of Chinese growth.
After discounting imports of parts, China’s exports of manufactured
goods increased from around 11 percent of GDP before the pandemic to 14 percent
of GDP in 2022. Predictions that this increase would turn out to be a one-off
pandemic-related surge have not been borne out: although export growth slowed
in 2023 as consumer spending diminished worldwide, it has now recovered, with
export volumes growing by over ten percent in the first part quarter of 2024.
China’s manufacturing surplus has increased even more dramatically, rising from
a low of around six percent of China’s GDP in 2018 to a stunning 10 percent in
2023.
China’s post-pandemic
export boom undermines the argument that the world’s economy is deglobalizing.
For all of China’s economic weaknesses, it can still produce goods at a scale
that no other country can match. After the end of a property boom that lasted
more than a decade, China responded to weakening internal demand by investing
more in the production of manufactured goods for export. Consider the
trajectory in one prominent sector: automobiles.
Historically, China
was not a major auto exporter. But as domestic automobile demand trended
downward, China went from being a net importer of automobiles to the world’s
largest exporter of them in just three years. This export wave is not about to
weaken: China can produce at least twice as many internal combustion cars as it
needs to meet shrinking domestic demand, and the country’s leading electric car
manufacturer, BYD, is doubling its production capacity to ramp up exports. It
is hard to think of a more potent symbol of China’s steadily growing
integration with the global economy than the enormous fleet of car carriers BYD
now has on order from Chinese shipyards.
Dodge Ball
U.S. policymakers are
rightly concerned that the world has become too reliant on China for supply,
particularly with respect to clean energy and green technology. In a mid-May
speech, Lael Brainard, the director of the U.S. National Economic Council, put
it well: “China’s industrial capacity and its exports in certain sectors are
now so large that they can undermine the viability of investments in the U.S.
and other countries. … Markets need reliable demand signals and fair
competition for the best firms and technologies to be able to innovate and
invest in clean energy and other sectors. The Chinese government has made clear
that China’s massive investments in electric vehicles, solar panels, and
batteries are an intentional strategy to effectively capture these sectors.”
Chinese policymakers
should be equally worried that their country’s economy has become too dependent
on the world for demand. But they do not appear to be. Chinese leader Xi
Jinping’s policy of supporting “new productive forces,” together with his
perhaps surprising resistance to “welfarism,” has yielded an unbalanced
domestic economy that increasingly must externalize its internal distortions.
China’s surplus in manufacturing has risen as much relative to world GDP in the
last few years as it did during the first China shock following the country’s
accession to the WTO, when a surge in Chinese exports and a sharp rise in
China’s manufacturing surplus displaced workers across the world’s advanced
economies. As a share of the world’s GDP, China’s manufacturing surplus now
substantially exceeds any other country’s recorded surplus since the end of
World War II.
China’s need to grow
through exports, however, is not the only explanation for globalization’s
surprising resilience. Another is corporate tax avoidance. Changes in the way
pharmaceutical companies behave are illuminating: U.S. pharmaceutical firms now
often sell the rights to profit from promising new drugs to subsidiaries
located in low-tax jurisdictions. These drugs are manufactured abroad and then
sold at a high price in the United States. As a result, the major U.S.
pharmaceutical companies—and other multinationals—now report earning almost all
their profits abroad and pay little or no domestic corporate income tax. This
particular form of globalization extends beyond the pharma industry: American
multinationals now often produce abroad in order to book large profits in
offshore tax havens.
The low-tax haven of
Ireland, and not China or India, is now by far the largest exporter of
pharmaceuticals to the United States: in 2023, the United States imported twice
as many pharmaceutical products from Ireland as it did from Canada, China,
India, and Mexico combined. The trend extends well beyond pharmaceuticals.
Ireland is also the biggest global market for the export of U.S.
research-and-development services. The Cayman Islands and the British Virgin
Islands are the biggest export markets for U.S. financial services, and Bermuda
is the United States’ main international supplier of insurance services. A 2017
International Monetary Fund study showed that the resilience of FDI flows in
the wake of the 2008–09 global financial crisis can largely be credited to a
steady rise in FDI flows through centers of corporate tax avoidance.
In 2015, the members
of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development agreed to change
their tax regulations to try to make it harder for companies to locate their
profits in zero-tax jurisdictions. But these changes, which were implemented at
the end of 2020, have not curbed tax-avoidance-driven globalization. Following
a tax strategy pioneered by Apple, a number of major U.S. companies directed
their Irish subsidiaries to buy their affected subsidiaries in zero-tax
jurisdictions, effectively “Ireland-shoring” their intellectual property while
simultaneously generating large depreciation allowances that lower their
effective tax rates in Ireland.
These moves have made
corporate tax avoidance more visible because Ireland is the only center of tax
avoidance that follows Europe’s rigorous standards for the disclosure of
economic and balance-of-payments data. Consequently, it is easy to track how
foreign multinationals’ profits in Ireland have soared from around 40 billion
dollars per year ten years ago to over 180 billion dollars per year today and
now constitute roughly 70 percent of Ireland’s real domestic economy. Even more
important, these profits represent over one percent of the eurozone’s GDP and
close to three-quarters of a percent of the United States’ GDP. The resulting
loss of U.S. tax revenue is far larger than most analyses capture, because
corporations have no incentive to highlight just how little tax they actually
pay in the United States.
Risk Reversal
Why does it matter if
many people, including political leaders and influential commentators,
misunderstand the trajectory of contemporary globalization and overstate the
impact of a decline in political support for further economic integration?
First, if policymakers focus discussion on the costs of deglobalization, they
risk overlooking the many unhealthy forms of globalization that still exist and
persist relatively undisturbed. China’s role in middle America’s
deindustrialization is now widely acknowledged. But the role that the U.S.
corporate tax code plays in that deindustrialization is not. Allowing American
corporations to continue to use tax-avoidance strategies that transfer profits
and production out of the United States is unhealthy for the global economy,
even if it boosts measures of U.S. trade and foreign investment. If, instead,
the U.S. Congress changed the tax laws to raise the global minimum tax and made
it harder to shift intellectual property created in the United States to
low-tax jurisdictions, U.S. pharmaceutical companies would likely shift the
production of their most profitable drugs out of locations such as Ireland and
Singapore and back to the United States.
Those who worry about
deglobalization also often assume that all forms of economic integration are
healthy. But they are not: the surge in cross-border bank flows before the
global financial crisis, for example, reflected an unhealthy level of leverage
and risk in the world’s big banks. Today, too, an excessive amount of the
world’s FDI flows merely reflect tax avoidance, not productive economic
activity.
There is also an
opposing risk: that if policymakers do not acknowledge the degree to which
globalization persists, they will grossly underestimate the shocks that would
stem from a fuller decoupling of Chinese and U.S. trade. Even with the rise in
U.S. tariffs on China, the world’s economy is still deeply integrated. If
anything, China has become more central to global trade since Trump imposed his
tariffs, and U.S.-Chinese interdependence has been masked, not severed. For
instance, China could not have achieved its current $800 billion trade surplus
in goods if the United States did not have a large trade deficit. That deficit
is no longer financed by the direct purchase of U.S. bonds by China’s central
bank. But it is still indirectly financed by China, in the form of the large
stockpiles of dollars that Chinese exporters now hold offshore. The way China
surplus’s remains the mirror image of the U.S. deficit is just one of the many,
complex forms in which the U.S. and Chinese economies continue to rely on one
another, even as the ties become harder to see in top-line economic data.
Some deglobalization
here could, in fact, also be healthy. If China relied less on global demand to
make up for its internal weaknesses, that would put less pressure on its
trading partners’ manufacturing sectors as well as reduce the overdependence of
the United States, most European countries, and other democracies on China for
critical inputs. But right now, the strong pressures on China to solve its
domestic economic problems by increasing exports are likely to keep driving the
world toward deeper, more unbalanced economic integration. The United States is
trying to resist this pressure in the realm of electric vehicles, at a cost to
U.S. consumers. As Chinese electric vehicle firms go global, however, it is not
clear that the United States can successfully insulate its own electric-vehicle
industry simply by imposing tariffs on bilateral trade. Avoiding
interdependence with China would likely require bigger policy shifts—and a
greater willingness to pay for the costs of regionally rather than globally integrated
supply chains.
Historically, the
trade in automobiles has always been more regional than global; preserving that
trading pattern in the face of a growing Chinese supply will require more
restrictions on trade. But those sectoral restrictions can only limit the
development of new forms of integration; they cannot reverse globalization writ
large. The biggest economic challenge China now poses to G-7 policymakers is
how to limit the dislocations that flow from China’s increasingly export- and
manufacturing-dependent economy. Discussions about deglobalization miss the
point.
For the United States
shortly, any true decoupling from the Chinese economy would be costly—far more
costly than the past few years superficial decoupling. An easy, and relatively
cheap, way for the United States to avoid bilateral tariffs is to import parts
from Vietnam that China has shipped there for final assembly. It would be much
harder to engineer Chinese parts out of U.S. supply chains entirely. And it
would be equally difficult for China to restructure its economy so it relies
more on internal demand.
Deglobalization
offers analysts a simple story to tell about changes to the global economy. But
the reality is more complex: put plainly, it is impossible for a global economy
characterized by a large U.S. deficit on one side and a large Chinese surplus on
the other to truly fragment. The world needs to have a healthy debate about the
drawbacks and benefits of economic integration. But that debate must start from
a frank acknowledgment that many characteristics of the contemporary global
economy still push toward more, not less, integration and that addressing these
factors will have real costs.
For updates click hompage here