By Eric Vandenbroeck
and co-workers
The World Economy Today
Coming on the heels
of the pandemic-induced economic slowdown, the inflation crisis of the past two
years seemed to catch much of the world by surprise. After three decades in
which prices grew slowly across the world’s advanced economies, the United
Kingdom, the United States, and the eurozone suddenly contended with nearly
double-digit inflation. Prices across many emerging markets and developing
economies have risen even faster, with inflation exceeding 80 percent in Turkey
and nearly 100 percent in Argentina.
True, the worldwide
inflation of the 2020s does not yet rival the worst inflation crises of past
decades. In the 1970s, annual price increases in the United States stayed above
six percent for ten years, reaching 14 percent in 1980; inflation in Japan and
the United Kingdom peaked at over 20 percent. For low- and middle-income
countries, the early 1990s were even worse: more than 40 such countries had
inflation rates above 40 percent, with some reaching 1,000 percent or more.
Still, in 2021 and 2022, the global economy is coming on the heels of the
pandemic-induced economic slowdown, and the inflation crisis of the past two
years seemed to catch much of the world by surprise. After three decades in
which prices grew slowly across the world’s advanced economies, the United
Kingdom, the United States, and the eurozone suddenly contended with nearly double-digit
inflation. Prices across many emerging markets and developing economies have
risen even faster, with inflation exceeding 80 percent in Turkey and nearly 100
percent in Argentina.
True, the worldwide inflation
of the 2020s does not yet rival the worst inflation crises of past decades. In
the 1970s, annual price increases in the United States stayed above six percent
for ten years, reaching 14 percent in 1980; inflation in Japan and the United
Kingdom peaked at over 20 percent. For low- and middle-income countries, the
early 1990s were even worse: more than 40 such countries had inflation rates
above 40 percent, with some reaching 1,000 percent or more. Still, in 2021 and
2022, the global economy moved in a deeply worrisome direction as governments
and policymakers belatedly discovered they were facing runaway price increases
amid the war in Ukraine and other
large-scale shocks.
Voters do not like
inflation or recessions. In an August 2022 Pew Research Center poll, more than
three out of four Americans surveyed—77 percent—said that the economy was their
number one election issue. Even in September, when prices in the United States
had stabilized somewhat, a poll led by Marist College found that inflation
continued to be voters’ top issue, ahead of both abortion and health care. As
with many elections, the 2022 midterms may ultimately hinge on noneconomic
issues; nevertheless, the state of the economy has significant predictive power
over voter preferences, and politicians know it.
Although much of the
debate about the new inflation has focused on politics and world events, the
question of central banks’ policies and the forces that shape them is just as
crucial. Many economists have assumed that inflation had been permanently tamed
for years, thanks to the advent of independent central banks. Beginning in the
1990s, central bankers in many countries began setting targets for the level of
inflation; a two percent goal became an explicit part of U.S. Federal Reserve
Bank policy in 2012. Indeed, well into the COVID-19 pandemic, most
regarded a return to the high inflation of the 1970s as implausible. Fearing a
pandemic-driven recession, governments and central banks were instead
preoccupied with jump-starting their economies; they discounted the
inflationary risks posed by combining large-scale spending programs with
sustained ultralow interest rates. Few economists saw the dangers of the
enormous stimulus packages signed by U.S. Presidents Donald Trump in December
2020 and Joe Biden in March 2021, which pumped trillions of dollars into the
economy. Nor did they anticipate how long it would take for supply chain
problems to sort themselves out after the pandemic or how vulnerable the global
economy would be to sustained high inflation in the event of a major
geopolitical shock, as when Russia invaded Ukraine. Having waited too long to
raise interest rates as inflation built up, central banks scrambled to control
it without tipping their economies and the world into a deep recession.
In addition to
suffering the consequences of myopic economic thinking, central banks have also
been buffeted by dramatic political and economic changes. The 2020s are shaping
up to be the most difficult era in central banking since the 1970s when the
global economy was contending with the Arab oil embargo and the collapse of the
postwar Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates. Today, large-scale global
shocks such as war, pandemic, and drought seem to be coming simultaneously or
simultaneously. Meanwhile, the forces of globalization that, for much of the
past 20 years, have helped sustain long-term growth have turned into headwinds
because China is rapidly aging and because of growing
geopolitical frictions between China and the United States. None of
these changes is good for productivity and growth, but they all contribute to
higher inflation now and well into the future.
By their nature,
supply shocks are difficult for central banks to address. In the case of a
simple demand shock—too much stimulus, for example—central banks can use
interest rates to stabilize both growth and inflation. With supply shocks,
however, central banks must weigh difficult tradeoffs between bringing down
inflation and the costs to businesses and workers of lower growth and higher
unemployment. Even if central banks are prepared to raise interest rates as
needed to tackle inflation, they have far less independence than they did two
decades ago. The 2008 financial crisis weakened central banks’
political legitimacy by undermining the idea that their policies ultimately
worked to benefit everyone; many people lost their homes and jobs in the worst
economic downturn since the Great Depression. As central banks today deliberate
how far to tamp down on demand, they have to consider whether they are willing
to risk causing yet another deep recession. If, during a recession, the
government’s social safety net is inadequate, doesn’t the central bank need to
take that into account?
Those who dismiss
such concerns as external to monetary policy have not been reading central
bankers’ speeches over the past decade.
Amid an unending
series of supply shocks, central banks may also be confronting a long-term
shift that neither policymakers nor financial markets have considered. Although
many of the immediate drivers of the extraordinary rise in prices in 2021 and
2022 will eventually dissipate, the era of perpetual ultralow inflation will
not come back anytime soon. Instead, thanks to a host of factors, including
deglobalization, rising political pressures, and ongoing supply shocks such as
the green energy transition, the world may very well be entering an extended
period in which elevated, and volatile inflation is likely to be persistent,
not in the double digits but significantly above two percent. Most central
bankers insist they can make no bigger mistake than allowing high inflation to
linger so long that it starts pushing long-term inflation expectations by any
noticeable amount. It is probably fair to say that most Wall Street economists
buy that argument. But they may face more painful choices over the next decade
and certainly in the immediate future. The social and political implications of
a central bank-induced deep downturn—after the two worst recessions since the
Great Depression (2008 and 2020)—are profound.
Passing The Bucks
Ever since U.S.
monthly inflation began to rise sharply in the spring of 2021, Washington has
been divided between those who blame it on excessive stimulus spending by the
Biden administration and those who maintain that global factors beyond
Washington’s control mainly cause it. Neither argument is convincing. The
stimulus view is overblown: today's countries have been experiencing high
inflation, despite vast differences in the extent to which they stimulated
their economies. Although their stimulus packages were considerably smaller,
the United Kingdom and the eurozone have had even higher inflation than the
United States, with Australia, Canada, and New Zealand only slightly lower.
Some have also pointed to the Biden administration’s clampdown on fossil fuel
pipelines and exploration as a contributor to inflation. However, the main
effects on production and output probably lie in the future.
Yet blaming inflation
mostly on Russian President Vladimir Putin’s war in Ukraine, Chinese President
Xi Jinping’s war on COVID-19, or post-pandemic supply chain breakdowns is also
wrong. Prices were already ramping up in the United States in 2021, long before Putin invaded
Ukraine. And inflation initially manifested itself in different countries in
very different ways. In much of the world, higher food and energy costs were
the main driving factors, but in the United States, the most pronounced price
increases came in rents, vehicles, clothing, and recreation. At this point,
second and third-round effects are working their way through the economy, and
price increases are radiating even more broadly across many sectors.
Many economists think
the real culprit was the Federal Reserve, which did not begin hiking interest
rates until March 2022; inflation had been rising sharply for a year. That
delay was a huge mistake, although more easily seen as such in hindsight,
knowing that the worst effects of the pandemic could have quickly been brought
under control. And the root of the mistake lies not just with the Fed and its
staff but also with a broad consensus within the economics profession, which
had become heavily wedded to the view that most of the time, it is far better
to have too much macroeconomic stimulus—high deficits, very low-interest
rates—than too little.
Almost no one has
questioned the massive spending programs implemented worldwide in the early
stages of the pandemic. The point of having governments preserve fiscal
capacity is precise. Hence, they have the resources to take large-scale actions
to protect the vulnerable in the event of a deep recession or catastrophe. The
issue is when to stop. Inevitably, stimulus spending is political. Those who promote
large rescue packages are often motivated by the opportunity to expand social
programs whose approval in Congress might, in ordinary times, be impossible.
This is why there tends to be far less talk about reducing stimulus once a
crisis is over.
As a candidate, Biden
pledged to expand government spending, partly to facilitate the post-COVID
economic recovery but mainly to share the benefits of growth more equally and
to put significant resources into the national response to climate change. As a
lame-duck president, Trump attempted to frustrate his winning
opponent’s ambitions by passing his own $900 billion COVID-19 relief package in
December 2020, even though the economy was already rebounding strongly. Three
months later, although the economy was recovering, Democrats under Biden passed
a new $1.9 trillion stimulus package, with several prominent economists,
including New York Times columnist and Nobel laureate Paul
Krugman, cheering them on. Krugman and others argued that the package would
enhance the recovery and provide insurance against another wave of the pandemic
and that it carried minimal risks of igniting inflation.
Let Them Spend
In early 2021, there
were reasons to question the prevailing wisdom about the Biden stimulus. Most
notably, Harvard economist and former U.S. Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers
warned that the contemplated bill could lead to inflation. Although severe
inflation had not occurred in decades, Summers had a simple and compelling
insight. Throwing trillions of dollars into an economy with severe supply
constraints and only a modest demand shortage had to be inflationary. If too
many people try to buy cars simultaneously and have the cash to do so, car
prices will rise.
A key element of
Summers’s logic was that the stimulus-fueled consumption binge would not be
satisfied by foreign suppliers, including China. Normally, when U.S. consumers
go on a spending spree, the U.S. trade deficit supplies at least a partial outlet
from internal price pressures: if U.S. demand exceeds U.S. production,
Americans can still buy from abroad. But in the spring of 2021, the
availability of foreign goods was limited, with the U.S. economy emerging from
the pandemic faster than most and global supply lines in even greater disarray
than domestic U.S. supply lines. Although economists have differed over the
precise figure, a reasonable guess is that excess demand accounted for as much
as half the cumulative rise in prices in the United States immediately after
the pandemic.
U.S. Federal Reserve Board Chairman Jerome Powell 2022
Faced with this vast
gap between demand and available supply, the Fed could have stepped in and
taken action. The Fed cannot change how the government chooses to allocate
stimulus funds or negate any inefficiencies it might entail. But it does have a
powerful instrument to prevent excess demand from creating high inflation,
namely the short-term interest rate, which it effectively controls. By raising
interest rates, the Fed makes it more expensive to borrow money, which in turn
lowers the price of all long-term assets, from equities to art. The most
important example of this phenomenon is the housing market, the largest
component of most Americans’ wealth. Higher mortgage rates make it more
expensive to buy houses, ultimately pushing home values. The resulting fall in
wealth reduces consumption. Higher interest rates discourage borrowing and
encourage savings, damping consumer demand. Higher interest rates also cause
firms to reevaluate long-term investment projects, directly and indirectly lowering
their demand for workers.
But before it decided
on a series of rate hikes, the Fed had to be confident that high inflation
was a serious risk. Despite Summers’s towering stature, his views made him an
outlier. Although a few respected economists, including former IMF Chief
Economist Olivier Blanchard, agreed with his warnings, Wall Street and most
academics discounted them. After all, inflation had not risen above four
percent for several decades, and many of the progressives that dominated Biden’s
economic team believed that the inflation effects of their stimulus would be
minor. What right did the Fed have to push back on a signature policy of an
administration that had come to office promising to help ordinary Americans and
that had the support of many progressive economists? Had the Fed started hiking
interest rates in spring 2021 and had a recession occurred for any reason—such
as a wrong turn in the COVID-19 pandemic—the Fed would have been subject to
withering criticism. It could potentially have compromised its future
independence. Given these considerations, it was hardly surprising that
the Fed hesitated to act.
Yet the Fed delayed action
even after it became clear that inflation was rising. By the fall of 2021—six
months after the Biden stimulus—the economy was rapidly heating up, yet the Fed
left interest rates untouched. It is hard to escape that Jerome Powell’s term
as Fed chair was set to expire at the end of the year, and Biden had not yet
announced his reappointment. Suppose Powell had chosen to initiate a cycle of
interest-rate hikes. In that case, it is entirely possible, indeed likely, that
Biden would have replaced him with a different chair, perhaps Lael Brainard. A
well-respected economist and prominent former treasury official in the Obama
administration, Brainard was viewed by financial markets as more dovish on
interest rates and more willing to risk inflation to sustain growth. In the
event, the Fed held back on raising rates, and Biden eventually reappointed
Powell. With Powell comfortably in his new term, the Fed only finally raised
interest rates in the spring of 2022. If the administration had wanted the Fed
to raise interest rates sooner, as some later argued it did, the right move
would have been to reappoint Powell in the summer of 2021, giving him a clear
mandate to act as the Fed saw fit.
Magical Monetary Thinking
Amid these pressures
from Washington, the Fed was also influenced by an increasingly dominant strand
of Keynesian economic theory that argued that there was considerable scope for
using macroeconomic stimulus more aggressively. Long before the start of the
pandemic, many economists had concluded that it was possible to significantly
increase government spending (and/or lower taxes) without raising interest
rates and causing inflation. After nearly a decade of ultralow interest rates
and low inflation, some thought that upward price pressures could be avoided
even if the spending increase was financed by “printing money”—having the
central bank pump money into the economy by buying up government debt. “Modern
monetary theory” is perhaps the best-known version of this approach, although
more moderate versions have already become mainstream.
One prominent idea
was that running the economy “hot” through high government spending and
ultralow interest rates could effectively reduce inequality. As low-wage
workers were brought into the labor force, they would gain skills that would
translate into higher lifetime earnings. The strong temporary stimulus could
thus result in permanent gains, or so many assumed. Support for this approach
was not limited to left-leaning policymakers. Trump’s economic team often
touted the effect of the strong, tax-cut-driven economy on incomes for low-wage
workers and minorities.
By 2019, when the Fed
gathered policy perspectives from leading academics as part of a review of its
fundamental monetary framework, many economists were studying how to stimulate
an economy stubbornly resistant to inflation and monetary stimulus, even after
interest rates had been taken to zero. Within the profession, there were
growing concerns about “lowflation”—inflation well
below two percent—a fear that became a major reason for the Fed’s inaction two
years later. Along with many academic economists, the Fed concluded that rapid
price increases were no longer a serious concern since it could always raise
interest rates to quell them, forgetting the difficulty of getting the timing
right and the political challenges that might ensue. In August 2020, the Fed
announced the results of its policy review, making clear that it would no
longer act preemptively to fight inflation just because labor markets were
tight but would wait until the economy showed clear signs that inflation was
taking root.
Despite its concerns
about lowflation, the Fed failed to embrace one
innovation that might have helped in the subsequent crisis:
negative-interest-rate policy. That is, it could have allowed very short-term
interest rates to go below zero to push up inflation expectations and
longer-term interest rates in a deflationary economy. It may seem
counterintuitive that such a tool could also help deal with inflation. But
suppose the Fed in 2021 had had such a “bazooka” in its arsenal, to paraphrase
former Treasury Secretary Hank Paulson. In that case, it could have been more
proactive in raising interest rates, knowing that if it overshot, it could cut
them as much as needed without running into the dreaded “zero bound.”
For
negative-interest-rate policy to be fully effective, several legal,
institutional, and tax changes would have to be implemented, and the Fed would
need the cooperation of the Treasury and Congress. The most important single
challenge is preventing significantly negative rates—say minus two percent or
lower—from causing investors to switch from bank accounts and Treasury bills to
paper currency, which has a zero interest rate. So far, even Japan and Europe,
which have tiptoed into negative rates, have avoided this issue, but two
solutions would prevent arbitrage into paper currency. One involves
establishing an exchange rate between paper currency and central bank reserves
(which are digital) that depreciates over time just enough to offset the fact
that, storage and insurance costs aside, the paper currency might otherwise
look good in a negative-interest-rate world. The other is to eliminate paper
currency while ensuring that free basic banking services are available to all,
either by introducing a central bank digital currency or by requiring banks to
offer free basic accounts to unbanked individuals (as, say, Japan does).
Between these two alternatives, it is likely possible to implement negative
rates as low as perhaps minus three percent simply by phasing out large
denomination notes (hundreds and fifties) and taking other regulatory steps to
make large-scale currency hoarding, in the billions of dollars, impractical.
In the event, the
adoption of a negative-interest-rate policy was deliberately taken off the
table in the Fed’s 2019 review out of fear of political repercussions. However,
if used effectively, it would help power the economy out of a deep recession.
(Indeed, the greater short-term stimulus would push up longer-term rates
because of higher growth and inflation expectations.) When the Fed next
reconsiders its policy framework, one hopes it will consider what legal and
institutional changes might be necessary to allow it to use such tools.
In short, the Fed’s
failure to respond to inflation in 2021 illustrates how much central bank
independence is often affected by political and intellectual
undercurrents—particularly during elections but also when the government in
power is subject to populist pressures. But it also shows that in today’s
environment, the Fed needs to expand its toolkit to stimulate the economy in a
severe downturn if it wants to strengthen its resolve to fight inflation when
it overheats.
Unmoving Target
One of the recurring
questions about the 2021–22 inflation has been whether the current trajectory
resembles the Great Inflation of the 1970s. How bad can it get? Central bankers
insist they will never allow the kind of complicity and complacency in economic
management that characterized that era. At the start of the 1970s, the chair of
the Fed at the time, Arthur Burns, recklessly expanded the money supply in what
many viewed as an effort to help President Richard Nixon get
reelected. Then, in 1978, Burns was succeeded by G. William Miller, who was so
focused on printing money to keep short-term interest rates low that he failed
to recognize that expectations of rising inflation were driving up long-term
interest rates as lenders demanded higher payments to keep up with inflation.
Under Miller, inflation in the United States rose to double digits.
Only with the
appointment of Paul Volcker, who succeeded Miller after a year and a half, did
the Fed begin to conquer the problem. Volcker is remembered for having raised
the Fed’s short-term policy rate above 19 percent, eventually bringing down
inflation from its peak of 14 percent in 1980. Far less noted, however, is that
the Volcker Fed initially held back, worried that causing a recession would
affect the 1980 presidential election; instead, it allowed inflation to rise
initially, possibly causing the later recession to be even larger. By 1982, the
Volcker Fed had brought annual inflation down to the three to 4.5 percent range,
remaining until Alan Greenspan took over as Fed chair in 1987. Notably,
although Greenspan is famous for having masterfully steered the economy while
lowering inflation even further, it took the Fed a while to get it to two
percent. Measured by the Consumer Price Index, annual inflation rose during
Greenspan’s first few years, reaching more than five percent before falling
decisively in the mid-1990s. True, it was arguably a much more difficult task
back then when high inflation expectations were deeply ingrained. In the
current crisis, inflation expectations have risen relatively modestly, though
central bankers remain concerned that they might rise much more.
At the time of the
Great Inflation, central banks also faced very different challenges. The
breakup of the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system in the early 1970s
removed any remaining link between currency and gold. Yet the United
States was among only a few countries with independent central banks for
which maintaining stable prices was an important part of their mandate. Over
time, this mandate has proven invaluable as a counterweight to political
pressures to hold down interest-rate increases, pressures that central bankers
again find themselves fighting today; politicians more often push central
bankers to take it easy on interest-rate hikes than beg for more, especially in
the year before an election.
The Federal Reserve Board Building 2022
Still, the current
inflation crisis and its predecessor have some remarkable similarities. Above
all, both eras were catalyzed by new kinds of supply shocks. The OPEC oil
embargo of 1973–74 was the biggest shock the global economy had seen since
World War II. Russia’s invasion of Ukraine has likewise shaken the foundations of the
global economic system, hugely exacerbating problems in global supply chains,
which were already frayed by the pandemic. And in both episodes,
Keynesian-oriented stimulus policies were in high fashion among academic
economists and policy commentators, with supply-side economics all but
forgotten.
Central bankers today
seem confident when they say they know how to bring inflation back to two
percent, but they are less convincing when they insist that they will not rest
until inflation returns to that target. They must realize that pushing up
interest rates risks creating a deep recession. And central bankers know that a
deep recession will fall particularly hard on low-income people, the young, and
workers from historically disadvantaged groups. In its new policy framework,
these are precisely the groups that the Fed aims to help. In light of recent
events, the Fed will need to reconsider this shift in emphasis, but helping
disadvantaged groups will certainly remain a priority.
Some economists argue that central banks should never
have formed a consensus around a two percent inflation target in the first
place and that a three or even four percent target would be better. According
to this view, by building higher expected inflation into interest rates,
central banks would have more room to cut rates in a crisis. It is a complex
debate with many nuances; raising the target rate could provide an alternative
to a negative-interest-rate policy. For central bankers, the drawback of such a
move is that having sworn up and down that they are committed to a long-run
inflation target of two percent, any change—particularly from a position of
weakness—might undercut their credibility, suggesting that the target could be
pushed even higher in the future. For this reason, if the economy stabilizes at
a higher rate of inflation for several years, central bankers are likely to say
that although they are tolerating moderately higher inflation for the moment,
they still intend to return to two percent in the future and will look for
practical ways to smoothly achieve it without causing a prolonged downturn.
There are other drawbacks to permanently higher inflation—wages and prices will
eventually adjust more often, making the monetary policy less powerful—and the
extra room to cut rates might still not be enough in a severe recession.
The Price Of Stability
One wonders how
prepared voters are for yet another deep recession for all their complaints
about inflation. The Fed is surely concerned about such an outcome. Another
risk is that long-term real interest rates—that is, inflation-adjusted rates,
which collapsed after the 2008 financial crisis—could continue moving back up
toward the very long-term trend, which tilts down at about 1.6 percent per
century, but nothing like the nearly three percent drop that occurred just a
few years after the financial crisis. This would make it more expensive for
governments to borrow money, pressure central banks to keep interest rates low,
and devalue government debt through inflation. Indeed, the changes in the
political and economic landscape have become so profound that it seems unlikely
for the foreseeable future that the Fed will choose to bring inflation down to
pre-pandemic levels and keep it there.
Monetary policy has a
big effect on politics; the economic cycle is a strong predictor of elections
almost everywhere in the world. But as the current crisis has made clear,
politics also affect monetary policy. The European Central Bank was doing
cartwheels to explain why it had to keep buying large quantities of debt from
countries on Europe’s periphery, most notably Italy. It initially marketed this
policy as necessary for deflation, but it has rebranded the program while
raising interest rates to fight inflation. The real reason for the policy, of
course, has always been to demonstrate the commitment of northern eurozone
countries to backstopping southern eurozone government debt, a profoundly
political goal. In the United Kingdom, Liz Truss, who became prime minister in
September 2022, has openly advocated reining in the Bank of England, just at
the moment when her fiscal policies are likely to place upward pressure on
long-term inflation.
The economist Milton
Friedman once opined that inflation is always and everywhere a monetary
phenomenon. That is, of course, a polemic overstatement. As the world is
witnessing, many factors affect inflation, including government spending
stimulus and global supply shocks. Central banks can bend long-term inflation
rates to their will if they are patient and independent. But it is unclear how
far they can go if the global economy continues to suffer seismic shocks. One
upside of this episode of high inflation is that it may increasingly force
politicians to recognize that low and stable inflation cannot be taken for
granted and that central banks must be allowed the freedom and focus necessary
to achieve their core mandate. Central bankers, for their part, should be more
open to using new tools such as an unrestricted negative-interest-rate policy
to fight severe recessions, tools that could help resist political pressures to
hold rates down in an overheating economy. Whether or not the Fed manages to
engineer a “soft landing” in the current crisis, the challenges it will face in
the coming decade will likely be considerably more complex than what it
confronted in the pre-pandemic world.
For updates click hompage here