By Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
The Trump Global Trading System
The sweeping tariffs
announced by U.S. President Donald Trump on April 2, along with the subsequent
postponements and retaliations, have unleashed an enormous amount of global
uncertainty. Much of the world’s attention is on the chaotic, short-term consequences
of these policies: wild stock market fluctuations, concerns about the U.S. bond
market, fears of a recession, and speculation about how different countries
will negotiate or react.
But whatever happens
in the near term, this much is clear: Trump's policies reflect a transformation
of the global trade and capital regime that had already started. One way or
another, a dramatic change of some kind was necessary to address imbalances in
the global economy that have been decades in the making. Current trade tensions
are the result of a disconnect between the needs of individual economies and
the needs of the global system. Although the global system benefits from rising
wages, which push up demand for producers everywhere, tensions arise when
individual countries can grow more quickly by boosting their manufacturing
sectors at the expense of wage growth—for example, by
directly and indirectly suppressing growth in household income relative to
growth in worker productivity. The result is a global trading system in which,
to their collective detriment, countries compete by keeping wages down.
The tariff regime
Trump announced earlier this month is unlikely to solve this problem. To be
effective, American trade policy must either reverse the savings imbalance in
the rest of the world, or it must limit Washington’s role in accommodating it.
Bilateral tariffs do neither.
But because something
must replace the current system, policymakers would be wise to start crafting a
sensible alternative. The best outcome would be a new global trade agreement
among economies that commit to managing their domestic economic imbalances,
rather than externalizing them in the form of trade surpluses. The result would
be a customs union like the one proposed by the economist John Maynard Keynes
at the Bretton Woods conference in 1944. Parties to this agreement would be
required to roughly balance their exports and imports while restricting trade
surpluses from countries outside the trade agreement. Such a union could
gradually expand to the entire world, leading to both higher global wages and
better economic growth.
During the Treaty
of Versailles John Maynard Keynes, not yet the world-renowned economist he
was to become, suggested that the Americans write off the money the British
owed them to reduce the need to extract reparations from the defeated and then
concentrate on getting Europe's economy going again.
Just six months after
the treaty was signed John Maynard Keynes published “The Economic Consequences
of the Peace”, the book that made his name. Today however Keynes’s critique of the Treaty of Versailles is seen as problematic. In fact, Keynes himself shortly after stated that he
regretted having written the book.
Keynes himself
regretted it, and so should historians and economists today. Mentioned in an
article early in 2017, telling to me that sometime in
1936, after the March 29 “election” in Germany which consolidated Hitler’s power,
Elizabeth Wiskemann, a German-born,
Cambridge-educated historian, met [Keynes] at a social gathering in London.
Suddenly, she reported later, she found herself saying, “I do wish you had not
written that book [meaning The Economic Consequences of the Peace, which the
Germans never ceased to quote], and then longed for the ground to swallow me
up. But he said simply and gently, ‘So do I’” 1
Keynes’s plan failed
to carry the day at Bretton Woods, largely because the United States—the
leading surplus economy at the time—opposed it. Today, however, there is a
chance to revive and adapt his proposal.
Mind the Gap
To understand what
ails the global trading system, consider how wages
shape an individual economy. Higher wages are usually good for the economy
because they boost demand for businesses while increasing their incentive to
invest in efficiency. The result is a virtuous cycle. The growing demand spurs
increased investment into ways of producing more with fewer workers, raising
economic productivity which, in turn, drives further increases in wages.
Individual
businesses, however, have different incentives. They can boost profits by
suppressing wages. The problem is that although lower
wages can benefit an individual business, they reduce the profits of others. In
an economy in which business investment is mainly constrained by whether there
is demand for more production, if businesses collectively suppress wages,
either household and fiscal debt must rise to replace the lost demand, or total
production and business profits will decline.
Although this
phenomenon, sometimes called Michal Kalecki’s Paradox
of Costs (named for the economist who first proposed it), mainly describes
businesses, it also applies to countries in a global economy. If suppressing
wage growth can make manufacturing in one country more globally competitive, it
can generate faster growth for that country by subsidizing and boosting
manufacturing exports. But if all countries suppress wage growth, growth in
global demand is reduced, and all countries suffer.
In a highly
globalized world where some states are more successful than others at
suppressing labor costs, the result is an asymmetry in the demand for and
supply of goods. Because businesses do not have to make products in the same
places where they sell them, local labor costs become crucial to the
competitiveness of manufacturers. Businesses that shift production to countries
where labor costs are lower relative to workers’ productivity can produce goods
more cheaply, making their products more attractive globally.
In any given state,
wage suppression puts downward pressure on domestic consumption while
subsidizing domestic production. This results in a rising gap between
production and consumption, which, if it remains within the economy, must be
balanced by raising domestic investment (which can further exacerbate the gap
between production and consumption). Otherwise, the gap invariably reverses,
either via raising wages or by cutting back on production.
But in a globalized
economy, there is another option: running a trade surplus. This allows the
country to export the cost of the gap between consumption and production to
trade partners. This is why, in 1937, the economist Joan Robinson referred to
the trade surpluses that resulted from suppressed domestic demand as the
consequences of “beggar-my-neighbor” policies.
It is also why, at
the Bretton Woods conference in 1944, Keynes
opposed a global trading system that allowed countries to run large, persistent
trade surpluses. A system that accommodated these surpluses, he said, would
encourage countries eager to expand manufacturing to subsidize it at the cost
of domestic demand. The result, Keynes explained, would be downward pressure on
global demand as countries fought to remain competitive by suppressing wage
growth. The countries most successful at doing so would become the winners of
global trade. Their share of global manufacturing would expand while that of
their trade partners contracts.
Keynes instead called
for countries to “learn to provide themselves with full employment by their
domestic policy.” In such a world, he argued, there would not be “important economic forces
calculated to set the interest of one country against that of its neighbours.”
At the time that
Keynes and Robinson were writing, the cost of beggar-thy-neighbor policies came
mainly in the form of higher unemployment, as higher exports, unbalanced by
higher imports, undermined manufacturers in trade deficit countries and forced
them to lay off workers. But after the world abandoned the Bretton Woods system
in the early 1970s, governments, including the U.S. government, learned to
allay the costs of unemployment either by lowering interest rates to encourage
consumer lending or through unrestricted deficit spending. The United States
thus disguised the employment consequences of running a consistent trade
deficit, but it did so through surging household and fiscal debt.
Export to Import
The link between the
internal imbalances of one country and those of its trade partners has
implications that economists sometimes fail to fully understand. In every
economy, internal and external economic imbalances must align, just as each
country’s external imbalances must align with the external imbalances of the
rest of the world. This means that countries able to control their internal
imbalances will at least partially drive the internal imbalances of trade
partners. It is why, in any globalized system, as the economist Dani Rodrik
has explained, countries must choose either more global integration
or more control over the domestic economy.
Within Rodrik’s
formulation, there are at least two very different ways of understanding
globalization. In the one most analysts assume
describes the world, major economies all chose to give up broadly the same
degree of control over their domestic economies in favor of more global
integration. Global trade is thus generally balanced as market forces reverse
government policies that create internal imbalances. If a country runs large,
persistent trade surpluses, for example, its currency will appreciate, or its
wages will rise, making its goods more expensive. That will, in turn, cause the
trade surplus to shrink as the welfare of domestic households expands.
In the other model of
globalization—one that better describes the world as it is—some major economies
exert less control over their domestic economies in favor of more global
integration, whereas others choose to retain control over their domestic economies,
perhaps by controlling wage growth, or determining domestic prices and
allocation of credit, or restricting trade and capital accounts. To the extent
that the latter set of states intervene to prevent their domestic economic
imbalances from reversing, they effectively impose their internal imbalances on
countries that retain less control over their trade and capital accounts. If
they choose industrial policies aimed at expanding their manufacturing sectors,
for example, they are also implicitly imposing industrial policies on their
trade partners, albeit ones which result in a relative contraction in those
partners’ manufacturing industries.
This is precisely the
kind of globalization that Keynes and Robinson opposed. It is the kind of
globalization that allows governments to pursue Kaleckian
strategies that are expansionary for their economies but contractionary for the
global economy as a whole.
If globalization is
to thrive, the world must revert to a kind of globalization where countries
export in order to import and where a country’s
production, consumption, and investment imbalances are resolved
domestically—not foisted onto trade partners. The world requires, in other
words, a new global trade regime where countries agree to restrain their
domestic imbalances and match domestic demand with domestic supply. Only then
will states no longer be forced to absorb one another’s internal imbalances.
The best way to
achieve this kind of globalization is to create a new customs union, along the
lines of what Keynes proposed at Bretton Woods. States that join would agree to
keep trade between them broadly balanced, with penalties for members that fail.
But they would also erect trade barriers against countries that don’t
participate to protect themselves from imbalances outside the customs union.
Trade would not be expected to balance bilaterally, of course, but rather
across all trade partners. Its members would have to commit to managing their
economies in ways that would not externalize the costs of their domestic
policies. In that system, every country could choose its preferred development
path, yet it could not do so in ways that inflict the costs of domestic
imbalances onto trade partners. (Smaller, less developed economies might
receive some limited exemptions from the union’s rules.)
Many countries,
especially ones that have structured their economies around low domestic demand
and permanent surpluses, might initially refuse to join such a union. But
organizers could start by gathering a small group of countries that comprise
the bulk of global trade deficits—such as Canada, India, Mexico, the United
Kingdom, and the United States—and bringing them into it. These states would
have every incentive to join, and once they did, the rest of the world would
eventually have to participate. If deficit countries refuse to run permanent
deficits, after all, surplus countries cannot run permanent surpluses. They
would instead be forced to raise domestic consumption
or domestic investment—either of which would be good
for global demand—or they would have no choice but to reduce domestic
overproduction.
If the world created
such a customs union, international trade “would cease to be,” as Keynes wrote,
“a desperate expedient to maintain employment at home by forcing sales on
foreign markets and restricting purchases.” The reason countries maximize exports
would no longer be to export the cost of subsidizing domestic manufacturing but
rather to maximize imports and household welfare.
If such a customs
union isn’t possible, however, the most likely outcome is the
beggar-thy-neighbor game predicted by Robinson in which states endeavor “to
throw a larger share of the burden upon the others,” as she wrote. “As soon as
one succeeds in increasing its trade balance at the expense of the rest, others
retaliate, and the total volume of international trade sinks continuously.”
That seems to be the
condition into which the world has been heading. It is what has delivered
Trump’s tariffs, along with rising trade complaints from people around the
globe. Until policymakers change the incentives for economies, international
trade tensions will not abate.
1. C.H. Hession, John
Maynard Keynes: A Personal Biography of the Man Who Revolutionized Capitalism
and the Way We Live, 1984, p. 306-7.
For updates click hompage here