By Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
As suggested, the US is forced to contemplate
a possibility that many have regarded as almost unthinkable
since the Cold War: a major military conflict with another great power. For
the first time in decades, Moscow has been rattling
its missiles to warn Washington about its support for Ukraine. And in early
August, following U.S. Speaker of the House Nancy Pelosi’s visit to Taiwan, Beijing dramatically escalated its threat of military
action over the island.
Almost as startling as the threats themselves are what they seem to
suggest about the limits of economic interdependence
as a force for peace. Both China and Russia rely to
an extraordinary degree on trade for economic growth and to secure their
positions on the world stage. China has managed to
quintuple its GDP over the last two decades in large measure through the export
of manufactured products; more than 50 percent of Russia’s government revenue
comes from the export of oil and gas. According to an influential strand of
thinking in international relations theory, these crucial economic ties should
put a much higher price on military conflict for both countries. Yet, at least
from appearances, neither power seems restrained by the potential loss of such
trade.
The picture is not as simple as it looks, however. Under certain
circumstances, trade relationships may serve as an inducement rather than a
deterrent to war. Moreover, the assertion of military power or even the threat
of adversarial confrontation does not always correlate with a rupture in
economic relations. As the contrasting cases of China and Russia have
demonstrated over the past year, economic ties often play out in ways that defy
expectations. For those who assume that commerce can help prevent great-power
conflict, it is critical to examine the complex ways that economic forces have
shaped strategic thinking in Beijing and Moscow.
Aggressive commerce
To understand how a trade might increase, not reduce, the chance of
military conflict, it is necessary to draw on the insights of realist theory.
In general, realism focuses on the struggle of great powers for relative
military power and position in a world that lacks a central authority to
protect them. But realists understand that
economic power is the foundation for long-term military strength and that international
commerce is vital for building an economic power base. For realists, trade can
have two major effects. First, by providing access to cheap raw materials and
profitable markets, trade can bolster a state’s overall economic performance
and technological sophistication, thus enhancing its ability to support
long-term military power. This is the upside to having a relatively open trade
policy. It explains why Japan, after the Meiji Restoration and China, after the
death of Mao Zedong, left behind the failed autarchic policies of the past and
sought to join the global economy.
But growing commerce also has a second effect. It increases a great
power’s vulnerability to trade sanctions and embargoes after having become
dependent on the import of resources and the export of goods for sale abroad.
This vulnerability can drive leaders to build up navies to protect trade routes
and even to go to war to ensure access to vital goods and markets.
As long as state leaders expect their trade relationships to remain
strong into the future, they will likely allow the state to become more
dependent on outsiders for the resources and markets that drive state growth.
This was the situation in Japan from 1880 to 1930 and in China from 1980 to the
present day. Leaders in both states knew that without significant commercial
ties with other great powers, including the United
States, neither could become important members of the great power club.
Yet if expectations of future trade turn sour and leaders come to
believe that the trade restrictions of other states will start to reduce their
access to key resources and markets, then they will anticipate a decline in
long-term economic power and military power. They may believe that more
assertive and aggressive policies are necessary to protect trade routes and
ensure the supply of raw materials and market access. This was Japan’s
predicament in the 1930s as it saw France, the United Kingdom, and the United
States retreating into increasingly closed and discriminatory economic realms.
As a result, Japanese leaders found themselves compelled to expand Japan’s
control over its commercial ties with its neighbors. Yet they also saw that
such moves made them look more aggressive, giving the United Kingdom and the
United States new grounds for restricting Japanese imports of raw materials,
including oil.
Today, China’s leaders understand that they face a similar dilemma—as
have the leaders of almost every rising state in modern history. They know
their foreign policy needs to be moderate enough to sustain the fundamental
trust that allows trade ties to continue. But they also need to project enough
military strength to deter others from severing those ties. The realist view of
how commerce affects foreign policy explains why Chinese leaders have been so
hostile over the past year to certain developments in East Asia—particularly
regarding Taiwan. In a more limited way,
this view can also help explain Russian President Vladimir Putin’s obsession with Ukraine.
Now or never
By most accounts, Putin’s war in Ukraine was driven by his fears about
Russian security—a concern that Ukraine was likely to join NATO in the near
term—and his desire to go down in history as the man who helped rebuild the
Russian empire. But the decision to launch the invasion was likely reinforced
in two important ways by something else: Russian energy exports to Europe.
First, Putin certainly understood that Europe was much more dependent
on Russia than Russia was on Europe. Before February, the European Union relied
on Moscow for approximately 40 percent of the natural gas it needed for its
industries and to heat its homes. The Russian economy was, of course, dependent
on selling this gas. But given the nature of the commodity, Putin could expect
that any significant reduction in the flow of natural gas would cause its price
to rise, hurting the EU in two ways—through reduced supply and higher costs—while
only marginally affecting the total revenue Russia would receive from its gas
exports. As the economist Albert Hirschman pointed out in 1945, about Germany’s
lopsided relationship with eastern European countries during the 1930s, in a
situation of asymmetrical interdependence, the less dependent state will likely
feel confident it can browbeat its more dependent counterparts into accepting
its hard-line policies simply because they need the
trade and are too weak to resist.
The fact that the Europeans continued to buy Russian gas and oil at
high levels after Russia annexed Crimea in 2014 suggested
strongly to Putin that they would not put up a fuss if he invaded Ukraine in
2022. He underestimated the ferocity of the European response. But Putin’s
awareness of Europe’s economic dependence on Russia, combined with the common
belief that Russia could handily beat Ukraine in a few weeks, helped give him
the confidence that his bold attack would succeed.
Second, Putin feared that Russia’s
economic leverage over Ukraine and Europe would decline in the future. In 2010,
huge natural gas deposits were discovered south of the eastern Ukrainian city
of Kharkiv and spread into the Donetsk and Luhansk Provinces. The field was
estimated to hold some two trillion cubic meters of gas, equivalent to the
total consumption of the 27-country EU over five years at current usage rates.
The Ukrainian government quickly changed state regulations to encourage foreign
investment. In 2013, it signed an agreement with Shell Oil to develop
the field, with ExxonMobil and Shell agreeing to work together on deep-water
gas extraction off the southeast coast.
Although Putin’s invasion of Crimea and the
Donbas in 2014 was probably motivated by other concerns, it was undoubtedly
clear in Moscow at the time that if Western firms developed the natural gas
deposits in eastern Ukraine, Ukraine would not only end its dependence on
Russian gas but also start to export its gas to the EU, thereby increasing its
bargaining leverage over its contracts with Moscow to allow Russian gas to pass
through Ukraine.
Of the three sets of pipelines, Russia uses to get its Siberian gas to
the EU—including one through
Belarus and another through the Baltic Sea to Germany—the most important history
has been the one through Ukraine, mainly because landlocked European countries
such as Hungary and Slovakia are especially dependent on Russian gas. Ukraine would reverse its
asymmetric energy relationship with Moscow by exporting its gas to the EU and
weaning itself from Russian supplies. And if Kyiv developed even informal ties
to NATO and the EU, let alone
joined one or both organizations, Ukraine would become a political threat to
Moscow and an economic threat in a position to undermine Russia’s long-term
economic power significantly.
In short, although Ukrainian President Volodymyr Zelensky’s moves in
late 2021 to increase his country’s political and economic ties with the West
certainly upset Putin’s sense of Russia’s
destiny and perhaps heightened Putin’s fear that liberal democracy might spread
into Russia, they also portended a significant loss in Russia’s ability to use
the energy card in the future. Expectations in Moscow that Russia might be
losing its economic leverage over Ukraine thus contributed to Putin’s sense
that it was “now or never” to absorb most of Ukraine east of the Dnieper River.
This area holds over 90 percent of Ukraine’s natural gas reserves.
Smaller chips, larger
stakes
By contrast, China’s economic
interdependence with the rest of the world is far more symmetrical than
Russia’s. The export of manufactured goods drives China’s economy. Like Japan’s
economy in the interwar period, China is exceedingly dependent on importing raw
materials to keep its economy going—including oil and gas from the Middle East
and Russia. China’s position as the world's workshop, supplying a significant
percentage of the world’s laptops, smartphones, and 5G communication systems,
gives the country some leverage with trading partners. It can threaten those
partners with selective restrictions on exports and imports when it dislikes
their foreign policies. But also, like Japan’s dependence on imports in the
interwar period, China’s dependency gives it short-term vulnerabilities unknown
in Russia. Economic sanctions can
certainly hurt Moscow, but its ability to sell oil and gas—at high prices
created by its actions in Ukraine—cushions the blow quite a lot.
If China faced anything close to the sweeping sanctions imposed on Russia,
its economy would be completely devastated. Beijing’s awareness of this
vulnerability is already a significant deterrent to its expansionist desires,
including its plans for an invasion of Taiwan. Consider the basic details of
China’s reaction to Pelosi’s visit to Taiwan, despite its prior threats.
Although Beijing demonstrated its anger with robust military exercises and
missile launches that passed into Taiwan’s airspace, it restricted its economic
response largely to sanctions on Taiwanese agricultural exports. Notably,
Chinese officials carefully avoided placing restrictions on Taiwanese
semiconductor exports since China depends on Taiwan for more than 90 percent of
its high-tech chips and a large portion of its low-level chips. And, of course,
China was careful not to sanction the United States directly for fear of
causing a new trade war that would exacerbate an already slowing Chinese economy.
Nonetheless, China’s economic dependency could lead it to take
aggressive action should Chinese expectations of future trade plummet. Take the
case of Taiwan’s high-tech semiconductors. China now has some capability to
produce chips with transistors that are under 15 and even under ten nanometers
in size. But to stay on the cutting edge of technological developments in
artificial intelligence, self-driving vehicles, and smartphone production, it
needs chips measuring under seven or under five nanometers, which only Taiwan can mass-produce at a
high level of quality. The latest Apple iPhone, for example, although it is
assembled in China, uses an Apple-designed five-nanometer chip that Taiwan
Semiconductor Manufacturing Company makes in Hsinchu, Taiwan.It
is not going too far to say that the whole future of China’s ability to catch up to the United States
depends on continued access to Taiwanese chips, just as Japan’s position in the
1930s was dependent on access to oil controlled by the Americans and the
British. And just as in 1941 with the American oil embargo, if Chinese
officials suspected that the United States might take steps to cut off Chinese
access to Taiwanese chips, they might determine that it is necessary to take
the island now to avoid long-term
economic decline. This is not some far-fetched scenario. In June 2022, a
prominent Chinese economist declared that if Washington placed sanctions on
China similar to those imposed this year on Russia, China should invade Taiwan
to secure possession of its chip-production facilities.
But here’s the good news. Chinese expectations for future trade, as Japanese expectations were in 1941, are a
function of American policy decisions. Suppose U.S. officials understand that
their policies directly shape how Beijing sees the future commercial
environment, not just in overall trade but in high-tech trade as it relates to
Taiwan. In that case, they can avoid making Chinese Communist Party leaders
feel their economy will collapse unless they act forcefully. The hostility that
can lead to war stems from choices, not given realities. By reassuring Beijing
that China will continue to
receive semiconductors from Taiwan—even if not the sophisticated machines from
the Netherlands needed to make them—the Biden administration can moderate
Beijing’s concerns about future trade and reduce the likelihood of crisis and
war.
Chinese President Xi Jinping and his cohorts will,
of course, object to even this U.S. posture since it leaves China dependent on
outsiders for the chips that are the foundation of a modern high-tech economy
and military power. Yet since an attack on Taiwan would not only invoke
economic sanctions that would jeopardize China’s trade ties with the Western
world but might also lead to the inadvertent destruction of the chip-making
plants themselves, China has every reason to moderate its behavior, if not its
rhetoric when it comes to the island’s status.
Making dependence less
dangerous
Given Europe's dependence on Russian oil and gas, Putin may have
thought the West would roll over on Ukraine. But Chinese leaders now know that
the Americans, the Europeans, and their global partners have the resolve
to punish invaders and that
attacking Taiwan might destroy everything the Chinese Communist Party has
achieved over the past four decades. History shows that great dependent powers
are cautious in their foreign policies when their leaders have positive expectations
about future trade since they know that trade will help build the state’s
long-term power base and increase the wealth of the average citizen. And Xi needs both to happen
if he is to maintain the legitimacy of one-party rule in China and the
stability of the state itself.
When great powers seek economic interdependence to help maintain peace,
they face a tricky balancing act. It is not enough to simply have high
levels of trade since dependent states such as Japan in the 1930s and China
today can be pushed into more aggressive policies if they determine that they
do not have sufficient access to the raw materials and markets the state needs
to sustain its position as a great power. Leaders of less dependent states such
as the United States must be careful not to signal that they are seeking to
keep the dependent state down—or worse, to push it into absolute and relative
decline, as President Franklin
Roosevelt’s oil embargo did to Japan in 1941. Yet an open
trade policy can also be a problem since it can help the dependent state catch
up in relative power and become a long-term threat, as U.S. administrations
from Barack Obama to Joe Biden have understood regarding China.
A better approach would be to push rising powers such as China to level the playing
field by ending practices such as currency manipulation, subsidies, and the
illegal appropriation of foreign technology while assuring these states that if
they act moderately in their foreign policies, they will continue to enjoy
access to the resources and markets they need for economic growth and domestic
stability. Great-power leaders must strive to establish trade relations that
allow states to grow in absolute terms and yet ensure that neither side fears a
significant decline in relative economic power that would leave it vulnerable
to external threats or civil unrest.
With the current tensions over Taiwan exacerbated by Xi’s
continued alignment with Putin, this may
be difficult. But as great-power diplomacy returns to a more even keel, Washington
can remind Beijing that it needs the United States and Western partners to
achieve its own economic goals—and that Washington will not exploit China’s
dependence to undermine those goals. Biden can assure Xi that
the lesson of 1941—that destroying a state’s expectations of future trade can
lead to war—has been learned on the American side. But he can also suggest that
Beijing learn from Japan’s mistakes in the 1930s and avoid the aggressive
policies that destroyed the international trust needed for healthy trade
relations. If leaders in Washington and Beijing can improve each other’s
expectations of trade and future behavior, many more decades of peace in East Asia
should be achievable.
For updates click hompage here