By Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
Trade Wars are Easy to Lose
When a country (USA)
is losing many billions of dollars on trade with virtually every country it
does business with,” U.S. President Donald Trump famously tweeted in 2018,
'trade wars are good, and easy to win.” This week, when the Trump
administration imposed tariffs of more than 100 percent on U.S. imports from
China, setting off a new and even more dangerous trade war, U.S. Treasury
Secretary Scott Bessent offered a similar justification: “I think it was a big
mistake, this Chinese escalation, because they’re playing with a pair of twos.
What do we lose by the Chinese raising tariffs on us? We export one-fifth to
them of what they export to us, so that is a losing hand for them.”
In short, the Trump administration believes it has what game
theorists call escalation dominance over China and any other economy with which
it has a bilateral trade deficit. Escalation dominance, in the words of a
report by the RAND Corporation, means that “a combatant can escalate a conflict
in ways that will be disadvantageous or costly to the adversary while the
adversary cannot do the same in return.” If the administration’s logic is
correct, then China, Canada, and any other country that retaliates against U.S.
tariffs is indeed playing a losing hand.
But this logic is
wrong: it is China that has escalation
dominance in this trade war. The United States gets vital goods from China
that cannot be replaced any time soon or made at home at anything less than
prohibitive cost. Reducing such dependence on China may be a reason for action,
but fighting the current war before doing so is a recipe for almost certain
defeat at an enormous cost. Or to put it in Bessent’s terms: Washington, not
Beijing, is betting all in on a losing hand.
Show Your Hand
The administration’s
claims are off-base on two counts. For one thing, both sides get hurt in a
trade war because both lose access to things their economies want and need and
that their people and companies are willing to pay for. Like launching an actual
war, a trade war is an act of destruction that puts the attacker’s forces and
home front at risk, as well: if the defending side did not believe it could
retaliate in a way that would harm the attacker, it would surrender.
Bessent’s poker
analogy is misleading because poker is a zero-sum game: I win only if you lose;
you win only if I lose. Trade, by contrast, is positive-sum: in most
situations, the better you do, the better I do, and vice versa. In poker, you
get nothing back for what you put in the pot unless you win; in trade, you get
it back immediately, in the form of the goods and services you buy.
The Trump
administration believes that the more you import, the less you have at
stake—that because the United States has a trade deficit with China,
importing more Chinese goods and services than China does U.S. goods and
services, it is less vulnerable. This is factually
wrong, not a matter of opinion. Blocking trade reduces a nation’s real
income and purchasing power; countries export to earn the money to buy things
they do not have or are too expensive to make at home.
A trading chart on the New York Stock Exchange, New
York, April 2025
What’s more, even if
you focus solely on the bilateral trade balance, as the Trump administration
does, it bodes poorly for the United States in a trade war with China. In 2024,
U.S. exports of goods and services to China were $199.2 billion, and imports
from China were $462.5 billion, resulting in a trade deficit of $263.3 billion.
To the degree that the bilateral trade balance predicts which side will “win”
in a trade war, the advantage lies with the surplus economy, not the deficit
one. China, the surplus country, is giving up sales, which is solely money; the
United States, the deficit country, is giving up goods and services it does not
produce competitively or at all at home. Money is fungible: if you lose income,
you can cut back spending, find sales elsewhere, spread the burden across the
country, or draw down savings (say, by doing fiscal stimulus). China, like most
countries with overall trade surpluses, saves more than it invests—meaning that
it, in a sense, has too much savings. The adjustment would be relatively easy.
There would be no critical shortages, and it could replace much of what it
normally sold to the United States with sales domestically or to others.
Countries with
overall trade deficits, like the United States, spend more than they save. In
trade wars, they give up or reduce the supply of things they need (since the
tariffs make them cost more), and these are not nearly as fungible or easily
substituted for money. Consequently, the impact is felt in specific industries,
locations, or households that face shortages, sometimes of necessary items,
some of which are irreplaceable in the short term. Deficit countries also
import capital—which makes the United States more vulnerable to shifts in
sentiment about the reliability of its government and about its attractiveness
as a place to do business. When the Trump administration makes capricious
decisions to impose an enormous tax increase and great uncertainty on
manufacturers’ supply chains, the result will be reduced investment into the
United States, raising interest rates on its debt.
Of Deficits and Dominance
In short, the U.S.
economy will suffer enormously in a large-scale trade war with China, which the
current levels of Trump-imposed tariffs, at more than 100 percent, surely
constitute if left in place. In fact, the U.S. economy will suffer more than
the Chinese economy will, and the suffering will only increase if the United
States escalates. The Trump administration may think it’s acting tough, but
it’s in fact putting the U.S. economy at the mercy of Chinese escalation.
The United States
will face shortages of critical inputs ranging from basic ingredients of most
pharmaceuticals to inexpensive semiconductors used in cars and home appliances
to critical minerals for industrial processes, including weapons production. The
supply shock from drastically reducing or zeroing out imports from China, as
Trump purports to want to achieve, would mean stagflation, the macroeconomic nightmare seen in the 1970s and during the COVID pandemic, when the
economy shrank and inflation rose simultaneously. In such a situation, which
may be closer at hand than many think, the Federal Reserve and fiscal
policymakers are left with only terrible options and little chance of staving
off unemployment except by further raising inflation.
When it comes to real
war, if you have reason to be afraid of being invaded, it would be suicidal to
provoke your adversary before you’ve armed yourself. That is essentially what
Trump’s economic attack risks: given that the U.S. economy is entirely dependent
on Chinese sources for vital goods (pharmaceutical stocks, cheap electronic
chips, critical minerals), it is wildly reckless not to ensure alternate
suppliers or adequate domestic production before cutting off
trade. By doing it the other way around, the administration is inviting exactly
the kind of damage it says it wants to prevent.
This could all be
intended as just a negotiating tactic, Trump’s and Bessent’s repeated
statements and actions notwithstanding. But even on those terms, the strategy
will do more harm than good.
The fundamental
problem with Trump’s economic approach is that it would need to carry out
enough self-harming threats to be credible, which means that markets and
households would expect ongoing uncertainty. Americans and foreigners alike
would invest less rather than more in the U.S. economy, and they would no
longer trust the U.S. government to live up to any deal, making a negotiated
settlement or agreement to de-escalate difficult to achieve. As a result, U.S.
productive capacity would decline rather than improve, which would only
increase the leverage that China and others have over the United States.
The Trump
administration is embarking on an economic equivalent
of the Vietnam War—a war of choice that will soon result in a
quagmire, undermining faith at home and abroad in both the trustworthiness and
the competence of the United States—and we all know how that turned out.
For updates click hompage here