By Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
Repeated financial
crises, rising inequality, renewed protectionism, the COVID-19 pandemic, and
growing reliance on economic sanctions have ended the post-Cold
War era of hyper-globalization. Russia’s invasion of Ukraine may have
revitalized NATO, but it has also deepened the divide between East and West and
North and South. Meanwhile, shifting domestic priorities in many countries and
increasingly competitive geopolitics have halted the drive for greater economic
integration and blocked collective efforts to address looming global dangers.
The international
order that will emerge from these developments is impossible to predict. It is
easy to imagine a less prosperous and more dangerous world characterized by an
increasingly hostile the United States and
China, a remilitarized Europe, inward-oriented regional economic blocs, a
digital realm divided along geopolitical lines, and the growing weaponization
of economic relations for strategic ends.
But one can also envision
a more benign order in which the United States, China,
and other world powers compete in some areas, cooperate in others,
and observe new and more flexible rules of the road designed to preserve the
main elements of an open world economy and prevent armed conflict while
allowing countries greater leeway to address urgent economic and social
priorities at home. More optimistically, one can even imagine a world in which
the leading powers actively work together to limit the effects of climate change,
improve global health, reduce the threat of weapons of mass destruction, and
jointly manage regional crises.
Establishing such a
new and more benign order is not as hard as it might sound. Drawing on the
efforts of the U.S.-China Trade Policy Working Group—a forum convened in 2019
by New York University legal scholar Jeffrey S. Lehman, Chinese economist Yang
Yao, and one of us (Dani Rodrik) to map out a more constructive approach to
bilateral ties—we propose a simple, four-part framework to guide relations
among major powers. This framework presupposes only minimal agreement on core
principles—at least at first—and acknowledges that there will be enduring
disagreements about how many issues should be addressed. Rather than imposing a
detailed set of prescriptive rules (as the World Trade Organization and other
international regimes do), this framework would function as a “meta-regime”: a
device for guiding a process through which rival states or even adversaries
could seek agreement or accommodation on a host of issues. When they do not
agree, as will often be the case, adopting the framework can still enhance
communication among them, clarify why they disagree, and offer them
incentives to avoid inflicting harm on others, even as they seek to protect
their interests.
Crucially, this
framework could be put in place by the United States, China, and other major powers, as they deal with various contentious
issues, including climate change and global security. As has already been shown
on several occasions, the approach could provide what a single-minded focus on
the great-power competition cannot: a way for rival powers and even adversaries
to find common ground to maintain the physical conditions necessary for human
existence, advance economic prosperity, and minimize the risks of major war,
while preserving their security.
Incentives to compete
are ever present in a world lacking a central authority, and the most potent
powers will no doubt continue to eye one another warily. If any significant
powers make economic and geopolitical dominance their overriding goal, the
prospects for a more benign global order are slim. But systemic pressures to
compete still leave considerable room for human agency. Political leaders can
still decide whether to embrace the logic of all-out rivalry or strive for
something better. Human beings cannot suspend the force of gravity, but they
eventually learned to overcome its effects and took to the skies. The
conditions that encourage states to compete cannot be eliminated, but political
leaders can still take action to mitigate them if they wish.
Fewer rules, better behavior
According to many accounts,
the international order that emerged in the 1990s has increasingly been eroded
by the dynamics of great-power competition. Nonetheless, the deterioration of
the rules-based order need not result in great-power conflict. Although the
United States and China both prioritize security, that goal does not render
irrelevant the national and international goals that both share. Moreover, a
country that invested all its resources in military capabilities and neglected
other objectives—such as an equitable and prosperous economy or the climate
transition—would not be secure in the long run, even if it started as a global
power. The problem is not the need for security in an uncertain world, but how
that goal is pursued and the tradeoffs states face when balancing security and
other vital goals.
It is increasingly
clear that the existing, Western-oriented approach is no
longer adequate to address the many forces governing international power
relations. The future world order must accommodate non-Western powers and
tolerate greater diversity in national institutional arrangements and
practices. Western policy preferences will prevail less, the quest for
harmonization across economies that defined the era of hyper-globalization will
be attenuated, and each country will have to be granted greater leeway in
managing its economy, society, and political system. International institutions
such as the World Trade Organization and the International Monetary Fund must
adapt to that reality. Rather than more conflict, however, these pressures
could lead to a new and more stable order. Just as it is possible for
significant powers to achieve national security without seeking global primacy,
it is possible and even advantageous for countries to reap the benefits of
economic interdependence within looser, more permissive international
rules.
In our framework,
major global powers need not agree in advance on the detailed rules that would
govern their interactions. Instead, as we have outlined in a working paper for
the Harvard Kennedy School, they would agree only on an underlying approach to
their relations in which all actions and issues would be grouped into four
general categories: those that are prohibited, those in which mutual
adjustments by two or more states could benefit all parties, those undertaken
by a single state, and those that require multilateral involvement. This
four-part approach does not assume that rival powers trust one another at the
outset or even agree on which actions or issues belong in which category.
However, successfully addressing disagreements within this framework would
increase trust and reduce the possibility of conflict.
The first
category—prohibited actions—would draw on widely accepted norms by the United
States, China, and other major powers. At a
minimum, these might include commitments embodied in the UN Charter (such as
the ban on acquiring territory by conquest), violations of diplomatic immunity,
the use of torture, or armed attacks on another country’s ships or aircraft.
States might also agree to forgo “beggar thy neighbor” economic policies in
which domestic benefits come at the direct expense of harm done to others: the
exercise of monopoly power in international trade, for instance, and deliberate
currency manipulation. States will violate these prohibitions frequently, and
governments will sometimes disagree on whether a particular action violates
an established norm. But by recognizing this general category, they would
acknowledge that there are boundaries to acceptable actions and that crossing
them has consequences.
The second category
includes actions in which states stand to benefit by altering their behavior in
exchange for similar concessions by others. Prominent examples include
bilateral trade accords and arms control agreements. Through mutual policy
adjustments, rivals can reach agreements that benefit each other economically
or eliminate specific areas of vulnerability, thereby making both countries
more prosperous and secure and allowing them to shift defense spending to
different needs. In theory, one could imagine a significant
power agreeing to limit specific military deployments or activities—such
as reconnaissance operations near the other’s territory or harmful
cyber-activities that could adversely affect the other’s digital
infrastructure—in exchange for equivalent limitations by the other side.
When two states
cannot reach a mutually beneficial bargain, the framework offers a third
category, in which either side is free to take independent actions to advance
specific national goals, consistent with the principle of sovereignty but
subject to any previously agreed-on prohibitions. Countries frequently take
independent economic actions because of differing national priorities. For
example, all states set their highway speed limits and education policies
according to domestic preferences, even though higher speed limits can raise
the price of oil on world markets and improving educational standards can
affect international competition in skill-intensive sectors. On national
security matters, meaningful agreements among adversaries or geopolitical
rivals artoughrd to reach, and independent action is
the norm. Even so, the framework dictates that such actions must be well
calibrated: to prevent tit-for-tat, escalatory steps that risk a destabilizing
military buildup or even open conflict, remedies should be proportional to
the security threat at hand and not designed to damage or punish a rival.
Of course, what one
country views as a well-calibrated response may be perceived as a provocation
by an opponent. Worse estimates of a rival’s long-term intentions may make it
hard to respond in a measured fashion. Such pressures are already apparent in
the growing military competition between the United States and China. Yet both
have powerful incentives to limit their independent actions and objectives.
Given that both are vast countries with large populations, considerable wealth,
and sizable nuclear arsenals, neither can entertain any realistic hope of
conquering the other or compelling it to change its political system. Mutual
coexistence is the only realistic possibility. All-out efforts by either side
to gain strategic superiority would simply divert resources from
critical social needs, forgo potential gains from cooperation, and raise
the risk of a highly destructive war.
The fourth and final
category concerns issues in which effective action requires the involvement of
multiple states. Climate change and COVID-19 are obvious examples: in each
case, the lack of an effective multilateral agreement has encouraged many
states to free-ride, resulting in excessive carbon emissions in the former and
inadequate global access to vaccines in the latter. In the security domain,
multilateral agreements such as the Nuclear Nonproliferation Treaty have
limited the spread of nuclear weapons. Because any world order ultimately rests
on norms, rules, and institutions that determine how most states act most of
the time, multilateral participation on many key issues will remain
indispensable.
Viewed as a whole,
our framework enables rival powers to move beyond the simple dichotomy of “friend
or foe.” Undoubtedly, states sometimes adopt policies to weaken a rival or gain
an enduring advantage. Our approach would not make this feature of
international politics disappear entirely for the major powers and many others.
Nonetheless, by framing their relations around these four categories, rival
powers would be encouraged to explain their actions and clarify their motives
to each other, thereby rendering many disputes less malign. Equally important,
the framework increases the odds that cooperation would grow over time. A
conversation structured along the lines we propose enables the parties to
separate potential zones of cooperation from the more divisive or contentious
issues, establish reputations, develop a degree of trust, and better understand
the preferences and motives of their partners and rivals—as can be seen
when considering concrete, real-world situations.
Strategic transparency
Several recent
conflicts demonstrate the advantages of our approach. Consider the U.S.-Chinese
competition over 5G wireless technology. The emergence of the Chinese company
Huawei as a dominant force in global 5G networks has concerned the U.S. and
European policymakers not only because of the commercial consequences but also
because of the national security implications: Huawei is believed to have close
ties to the Chinese security establishment. But the hard-line
response by the United States—which has sought to cripple Huawei’s
international activities and pressure U.S. telecommunications operators not to
do business with the company—has only ratcheted tensions. By contrast, our
framework, although it would allow Western countries considerable latitude in
limiting the activities of Chinese firms such as Huawei within their own
countries, mainly on national security grounds, would also restrict attempts by
the United States and its allies to undermine Chinese industries through
deliberate and poorly justified international restrictions.
The promise of a
better-calibrated strategy for dealing with the Huawei conflict has already
been shown. In contrast to the actions taken by Washington, the British
government entered an arrangement with Huawei in which the company’s products
in the British telecommunications market undergo an annual security evaluation.
The evaluations are conducted by the Huawei Cyber Security Evaluation Centre,
whose governing board includes a Huawei representative and senior officials
from the British government and the United Kingdom’s telecommunications sector.
If the annual evaluation finds areas of concern, officials must make them
public and state their rationale. Thus, the 2019 HCSEC report found that
Huawei’s software and cybersecurity system posed risks to British operators and
would require significant adjustments to address those risks. In July 2020, the
United Kingdom decided to ban Huawei from its 5G network.
Ultimately, the
decision may have had less to do with the hcsec
report than direct U.S. pressure. However, this example still illustrates
the possibilities of a more transparent and less contentious approach. The
technical reasoning on which a national security determination was made could
be seen and evaluated by all parties, including domestic firms with a
commercial stake in Huawei’s investments, the Chinese government, and Huawei
itself. This feature alone can help build trust as each party develops a fuller
understanding of the motives and actions of the others. Transparency can also
make it more difficult for home governments to invoke national security
concerns as a cover for purely protectionist commercial considerations. And it
may facilitate reaching mutually beneficial bargains in the long run.
Nonetheless, most
actions in the high-tech sector are likely to end up in our third category, in
which states take unilateral measures to advance or protect their interests.
Here, our framework requires the responses to be proportionate to actual or
potential harms rather than a means to gain strategic advantage. The Trump
administration violated this principle by barring U.S. corporations from
exporting microchips and other components to Huawei and its suppliers,
regardless of where they operated or the purposes for which their products were
used. Instead of seeking to protect the United States from espionage or
cyberattack, the clear intention was to deliver a fatal blow to Huawei by
starving it of essential inputs. Moreover, the U.S. campaign has had severe
economic repercussions for other countries. Many low-income countries in Africa
have benefited from Huawei’s relatively inexpensive equipment. Since U.S.
policy has important implications for these countries, Washington should
have engaged in a multilateral process that acknowledged the costs that
cracking down on Huawei would inflict on others. This approach would have
conserved global goodwill to U.S. national security at little cost.
Acting, not escalating
Our framework also
suggests how the troubled relationship between the United States and Iran might
be improved to benefit both parties. For starters, the present level of
suspicion could be reduced if both sides publicly committed not to attempt to
overthrow the other and to refrain from acts of terrorism or sabotage on the
other’s territory. An agreement should be easy to reach, at least in principle,
given that the UN Charter already prohibits such actions. Iran also lacks the
capacity to attack the United States directly, and past U.S. efforts to
undermine the Islamic Republic have repeatedly failed.
Turkish President
Tayyip Erdogan meeting with Ukrainian President Volodymyr Zelenskiy in Lviv,
August 2022
Although short-lived,
the 2015 nuclear deal showed how even hardened adversaries could be brought
together on a contentious issue through mutually beneficial adjustments. The
deal, known as the Joint Comprehensive Plan of Action (JCPOA), was a perfect
illustration of this negotiated approach: China, France, Germany, Russia, the
United Kingdom, the United States, and the European Union agreed to lift
economic sanctions linked to Iran’s nuclear program, and Iran agreed to reduce
its stockpile of enriched uranium and dismantle thousands of nuclear
centrifuges, substantially lengthening the time it would take Tehran to produce
enough weapons-grade uranium to build a bomb.
U.S. Presiden Joe Biden speaking virtually with Chinese
leader Xi Jinping in Washington, November 2021
The JCPOA’s
proponents hoped the agreement would lead to a broader discussion of other
areas of dispute: subsequent negotiations, for example, could have constrained
Iran’s ballistic missile programs and other regional activities in exchange for
further sanctions relief or the restoration of diplomatic relations. At a
minimum, talks along these lines would have allowed both sides to explain and
justify their positions and given each a clearer understanding of the other’s interests,
redlines, and sensitivities. Unfortunately, these possibilities were foreclosed
when the Trump administration unilaterally abandoned the JCPOA in March 2018.
Skeptics might claim
that the fate of the JCPOA reveals the limits of this approach. They might
argue that had the agreement been in both sides’ interests, it would still be
in effect today. But the shortsighted U.S. withdrawal left both sides worse
off. Iran is much closer to producing a bomb than it was when the JCPOA was in
force, the two countries are if anything, even more, suspicious of each other,
and the risk of war is arguably higher. Even an objectively beneficial
agreement will not endure if one or both parties do not understand its merits.
Given the current
state of relations, the United States and Iran will continue to act
independently to protect their interests. Still, there is reason to believe
that both sides understand the principle that unilateral actions should be
proportional. When the United States left the JCPOA in 2018, Iran did not
respond by immediately restarting its entire nuclear program. Instead, it
adhered to the original agreement for months afterward, hoping that the United
States would reconsider or that the other signatories would fulfill its terms.
When this did not occur, Iran left the agreement in an incremental and visibly
reversible fashion, signaling its willingness to return to full compliance if
the United States did so. Iran’s reaction to the Trump administration’s
“maximum pressure” campaign was also measured. For example, the U.S.
assassination of the high-ranking Iranian general Qasem
Soleimani by a drone strike did not lead Iran to escalate; on the contrary, its
response was limited to nonlethal missile attacks on bases
housing U.S. forces
in Iraq. The United States had occasionally shown restraint as well, as when
the Trump administration chose not to retaliate when Iran downed a U.S.
reconnaissance drone in June 2019. Despite deep animosity, up to now, both
sides have recognized the risks of escalation and the need to calibrate their
independent actions carefully.
From aggression to mediation
There is no question
that Russia’s war in Ukraine has
darkened the prospects for constructing a more benign world order. Moscow’s
aggression was a clear violation of the UN Charter, and some Russian
troops appear guilty of wartime atrocities. These actions demonstrate that even
well-established norms against conquest or other war crimes do not always
prevent them. Yet the international response to the invasion shows that trampling
on such norms can have powerful consequences.
The war also
highlights the importance of our second category—negotiation and mutual
adjustments—and what can happen when states do not fully exploit this option.
Western officials engaged with their Russian counterparts on several occasions
before Russia’s invasion. Still, they did not address Moscow’s stated
concern—namely, the threat it perceived from Western efforts to bring Ukraine
into NATO and the EU. For its part, Russia made far-reaching demands that
seemed to offer little room for negotiation. Instead of exploring a genuine
compromise on this issue—such as a formal pledge by Kyiv and its Western allies
that Ukraine would remain a neutral state combined with a de-escalation by
Russia and renewed negotiations over the status of the territories Russia
seized in 2014—both sides hardened their existing positions. On 24 February,
2022, Russia launched its illegal invasion.
The failure to
negotiate a compromise via mutual negotiation left Russia, Ukraine, and the
Western powers in our framework’s third category: independent action. Russia
unilaterally invaded Ukraine, and the United States and NATO responded by
imposing unprecedented sanctions on Russia and sending billions of dollars of
arms and support to Ukraine. In keeping with our approach, however, even amid
this fierce conflict, each side has thus far sought to avoid escalation. At the
outset, the Biden administration declared that it would not send U.S. troops to
fight in Ukraine or impose a no-fly zone; Russia refrained from conducting
widespread cyberattacks, expanding the war beyond Ukrainian territory, and
using weapons of mass destruction. As the war has continued, however, this
sense of restraint has begun to break down, with U.S. Secretary of Defense Lloyd
Austin asserting that the United States has sought to weaken Russia over the
long term and Russian officials hinting about the use of nuclear weapons and
indicating that their war aims may be expanding.
Unilateral action in
Ukraine has also caused significant harm to third parties. By dramatically
raising the cost of energy, Western sanctions on Russia have dealt a severe
blow to the economies of low- and middle-income countries, many already
devastated by the COVID-19 pandemic. And Russian blockades of grain
shipments out of Ukraine have exacerbated a growing world food crisis. Because
the war has affected many other countries, ending the fighting and lifting
sanctions will likely require multilateral engagement. Turkey has already
helped mediate an agreement to allow the resumption of Ukrainian grain exports.
States that rely on these exports will no doubt seek arrangements that make
future disruptions less likely. If a Ukrainian pledge to remain neutral is part
of the deal, it must be endorsed by the United States and other NATO members. Kyiv will undoubtedly want assurances from its
Western backers and other interested third parties or perhaps an endorsement in
the form of a un Security.
Great powers, greater understanding
The war in Ukraine is
a sobering reminder that a framework such as ours cannot produce a more benign
world order by itself. It cannot prevent states from blundering into a costly
conflict or missing opportunities to improve relations. But using these broad
categories to guide great-power ties, instead of trying to resurrect a
U.S.-dominated liberal order or impose new global governance norms from above,
has many advantages. In part, because the requirements for adhering to it are
so minimal, the framework can reveal whether rival powers are seriously
committed to creating a more benign order. A state that rejects our approach
from the start or whose actions within it show that its expressed commitments
are bogus would incur severe reputational costs and risk provoking greater
opposition over time. By contrast, states that embrace the framework and
implement its simple principles in good faith would be regarded by others more
favorably and would likely retain greater international support.
Perhaps nowhere are
the potential benefits of our framework more apparent than in U.S.-Chinese
relations. Until now, the United States has failed to
articulate a China policy aimed at safeguarding vital U.S. security and
economic interests that do not also aim at restoring U.S. primacy by
undermining the Chinese economy. Far from accommodating China within a
multipolar system of flexible rules, the current approach seeks to contain
China, reduce its relative power, and narrow its strategic options. When the
United States convenes a club of democracies aimed openly against China, it
should not be surprising that Chinese President Xi Jinping cozies up to Russian
President Vladimir Putin.
This is not the only
way forward, however. China and the United States have emphasized the need to
cooperate in key areas even as they compete in others, and our approach
provides a practical template for doing just that. It directs the two rivals to
look for points of agreement and actions that both recognize should be
proscribed; it encourages them to seek mutually beneficial compromises, and it reminds
them to keep their independent actions within reasonable limits. By committing
to our framework, the United States and China would be signaling a shared
desire to limit areas of contention and avoid a spiral of ever-growing
animosity and suspicion. In addition to cooperating on climate change, pandemic
preparedness, and other shared interests and refraining from overt attempts to
undermine each other’s domestic prosperity or political legitimacy, Washington
and Beijing could pursue a variety of arms control, crisis management, and
risk-reduction measures through a process of negotiation and adjustment.
On the thorny issue of Taiwan, the United States
should continue the deliberately ambiguous policy it has followed since the
1972 Shanghai Communiqué—aiding Taiwanese defense efforts and condemning
attempts by Beijing at forced reunification while opposing unilateral Taiwanese
independence. Abandoning this policy in favor of more immediate recognition of
Taiwan risks provoking a war in which no one would benefit. Our
flexible approach would not help if China decides to invade Taiwan for purely
internal reasons—but it would make it less likely that Beijing would take this
fateful step in response to its security concerns.
Members of the
Chinese People’s Liberation Army in Tiananmen Square, Beijing, September 2021
Managing U.S.-Chinese
security competition has a multilateral dimension, as well. Although Asian
countries are concerned by China’s rising power and want U.S.
protection, they do not want to choose between Washington and Beijing. Efforts
to strengthen the U.S. position in Asia are bound to be alarming to China.
Still, the magnitude of its concerns and the intensity of its response are not
predetermined, and minimizing them (to the extent possible) is in everyone’s
interest. As Washington strives to shore up its Asian alliances, it should also
support regional efforts to reduce tensions in Asia and encourage its allies to
avoid unnecessary quarrels with China or one another. U.S.-promoted regional
trade deals, such as the newly launched Indo-Pacific Economic Framework for
Prosperity, should focus on maximizing economic benefits rather than trying to
isolate and exclude China.
Although we have
emphasized state-to-state relations in this discussion, our approach could be
equally productive for nonstate actors, civil society organizations, academics,
thought leaders, and anyone with a stake in a particular issue. It encourages
global community members to go beyond the stark antinomy of conflict versus
cooperation and focus on practical questions: What actions should be prohibited
outright? What compromises or adjustments would be feasible and mutually
beneficial? When is independent action expected and legitimate, and how can
well-calibrated actions be distinguished from excessive actions? And when will
preferred outcomes require multilateral agreements to ensure that third parties
are not adversely affected by the agreements or actions undertaken by others?
Such conversations will not produce immediate or total consensus. Still, more
structured exchanges on these questions could clarify tradeoffs, elicit
clearer explanations or justifications for competing positions, and increase
the odds of reaching mutually beneficial outcomes.
It is possible—some
would say likely—that mutual suspicion, incompetent leadership, ignorance, or
sheer bad luck will combine to produce a future world order that is
significantly poorer and substantially more dangerous than the present one. But
such an outcome is not inevitable. The tools are available if political leaders
and the countries they represent genuinely wish to construct a more prosperous
and secure world.
For updates click hompage here