By Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
Many countries have
been roiled in recent years by what is often called a “populist wave.” In the
Anglophone world, this new era began in 2016 with the Brexit vote in the United
Kingdom and the election of Donald Trump as president of the United States.
Media and political elites shocked by these events tied themselves in knots
trying to figure out what had happened and why. According to the most popular
strand of this thinking, the Brexit vote and Trump’s victory were the
reverberations of a profound economic and social transformation. Globalization
and technological change had shattered the livelihoods of working-class people
and eviscerated their communities, provoking a groundswell of anger and
resentment, a populist rejection of the status quo and the political
establishment. Since then, observers have been quick to find further evidence
of the surging force of populism in an ever-lengthening list of countries,
including Brazil, Hungary, India, Italy, and Sweden. An electoral surge for a
supposedly populist party anywhere in the world renews the drumbeat of alarm
that populism is submerging established party systems and, ominously, democracy
itself.
And yet for all the
alarm that populism has generated, its nature and political significance are
widely misunderstood. The metaphor of a “populist wave” reflects this error. It
exaggerates the electoral success of populism around the world, which has been
rather more modest than it sometimes appears. It also exaggerates the coherence
of populism as a political tendency, overlooking the extent to which ostensibly
populist entrepreneurs in different times and places have appealed to distinct
grievances. Even more important, the metaphor overstates the implications of
populist parties’ electoral successes for policymaking and democratic
stability.
Those panicking about
the rise of populism tend to imagine that shifts in public opinion fuel the
success of populist parties and figures; the public’s broadening antipathy to
globalization, immigration, integration (in the European context), and the political
class threatens to empower extremists and undermine democracy. But that is
demonstrably not the case. Public opinion in the West on most typically
“populist” issues has remained relatively stable for decades, belying the
notion that a new surge of popular discontent is remaking the political
landscape. Both in the United States and in many parts of Europe, the
gains of populist and far-right forces have less to do with a genuine shift in
political beliefs among the public than they do with changing elite politics.
In other words, top-down developments, not bottom-up ones, drive populism: an
expanded menu of political alternatives for voters, more effective mobilization
of long-standing discontents, and the tendency of mainstream political leaders
to concede in the face of challenges that are sometimes more illusory than
real.
A protest in Paris on Sunday night 20 October against
the far right.
Liberal democracies
do face genuine threats, including the potential erosion of important
democratic norms and institutions. And citizens of democracies have long prized
their own well-being and values over the defense of democratic procedures. But
their passivity is to be expected, not understood as a sign of rebellion
against the status quo. The political successes of populist groups and leaders
do not in themselves augur democracy’s demise. Misconstruing the nature and
appeal of populism muddles a clearer understanding of the contemporary
political landscape and distracts attention from the chronic vulnerabilities of
democracy—notably, the perennial temptation for political leaders to entrench
themselves in power.
The Mythical Surge
The emergence of
populist parties as significant electoral players in many parts of the world
has been a shock to the unusually stable party systems of the post–World War II
era, but in the longer arc of democratic politics, it should hardly be
surprising. Across Europe, for example, the average vote share for right-wing
populist parties has increased by less than half a percentage point per year
since the turn of the century. The rise of social democratic parties in many of
these same countries in the early twentieth century was far more dramatic by
comparison.
The impression of a
relentless surge in support for populist parties is partly a product of media
hype. The international press is fascinated and alarmed by their successes but
mostly tends to ignore their struggles and downturns. The New
York Times’ coverage of the 2023 election in Spain provides a striking
illustration of this habit. Two weeks before the election, the Times rolled
out a long front-page story portraying the rise of Vox, a far-right party, as
“part of an increasing trend of hard-right parties surging in popularity.” The
morning of the election, the Times ran another long front-page
story whose headline touted a “Far Right Poised to Rise.” But the next day,
after Vox fared poorly in the vote, the election result itself was reported
only in a brief article on page 8.
The media’s
fascination with populism doesn’t just warp conventional wisdom; it can have
real consequences at the polls. British political scientists studying media
coverage of the United Kingdom’s pro-Brexit UK Independence Party found that
its electoral successes received “disproportionate attention” in the press,
which in turn helped generate additional popular support. Insurgent parties
thrive on the perception that they are viable alternatives to the status quo,
and journalists unwittingly stoke that perception. See for example also
in Paula de Santander in Bogota.
The press also
routinely misinterprets shifts in electoral support for populist parties as
evidence of momentous changes in public opinion. In fact, there is remarkably
little relationship between support for these parties at the polls and
underlying populist sentiment—the specific attitudes, such as antipathy toward
immigrants, distrust of politicians, and nationalism (and in Europe, opposition
to further European integration) that generally predict individual support for
contemporary populist parties. That incongruity is paradoxical. How can the
factors that account for populist support at the individual level not do so in
the aggregate?
Victor Orban
That is because
support for populist parties depends on factors beyond the predispositions of
voters. In particular times and places, populist parties succeed or fail mostly
as a result of the quality of their leadership, the alternatives voters have to
choose from, and the strategic incentives provided by electoral systems. These
parties have long flourished in a variety of places where populist sentiment is
relatively scarce. The Swiss People’s Party, for instance, has garnered 25 to
30 percent of the vote in each of the past six elections—more than any other
populist party in western Europe—despite Switzerland’s unusually high levels of
trust in politicians and satisfaction with the economy, the government, and
democracy. Populist parties in Denmark, Norway, and Sweden are among the most
successful in Western Europe despite those countries having the continent’s
most favorable attitudes toward immigrants. Conversely, populist parties were
slow to emerge in Belgium, Ireland, Portugal, and Spain—all places where public
opinion exhibited more widespread populist sentiment.
In majoritarian
democracies, winning parties are generally broad coalitions of diverse
interests, and it is hard to gauge how much of a party’s support can be
ascribed to “populist” rhetoric or policy positions. In the United States, for
example, the Republican nominee for president won 46 percent of the popular
vote in 2016 and 47 percent in 2020, but that is a testament to the strength of
partisan loyalties in the current, highly polarized political environment, not
to the specific appeal of populism or Trump. Trump won the 2016
Republican nomination with intense factional support in a crowded field, then
mostly relied on the backing of traditional Republicans to defeat an unpopular
Democratic opponent, Hillary Clinton, in the general election. Although the
Republican Party has indeed reflected an increasingly populist cast in recent
years, that is probably more a product than a cause of Trump’s success; loyal
partisans are notoriously susceptible to cues from party leaders.
Republicans’ shifting
views regarding Russian President Vladimir Putin during Trump’s
presidency provide a remarkable example. A 2014 survey by YouGov and The
Economist found just ten percent of Republicans expressed favorable
views of Putin. But in December 2016, after over a year of Trump’s pro-Putin
campaign rhetoric, that number was up to 37 percent. It seems far-fetched to
imagine that the party of Ronald Reagan was transformed by an autonomous
groundswell of enthusiasm for the Russian dictator; rather, Trump supporters
were swayed by the president’s peculiar fondness for Putin. Effects of this
sort are not limited to the domain of foreign policy. In the early days of
Trump’s presidency, the political scientists Michael Barber and Jeremy Pope
tested the reactions of rank-and-file Republicans to information about his
positions on a variety of major issues, including immigration, health care,
guns, and abortion. They found substantial shifts in preferences, especially
among the most committed and least informed partisans, in the direction of
positions ascribed to Trump, regardless of whether those positions were
conservative or liberal. “Many people’s expressed issue positions,” they
concluded, “are malleable to the point of issue innocence.”
The Myth of Economic Disaffection
The common invocation
in Western media of a “populist wave” encourages observers to imagine that
there is some single driving force propelling the various manifestations of
populism seen around the globe in recent years. In fact, populism is a
political language and style adaptable to a wide array of circumstances. In
most democracies most of the time, there is a substantial reservoir of
potential support for challenges to the status quo, and populists draw on that
reservoir opportunistically to build their brands and jostle for power.
The most frequent
explanation for the so-called populist wave is widespread economic disaffection
stemming from deindustrialization, globalization, and technological change.
This explanation appeals to observers for a number of reasons: it gratifies
nostalgia for an orderly postwar era in which economic issues shaped the party
systems of affluent democracies; it invites leftists to chastise so-called
neoliberals for the policy errors of the late twentieth century; and it
submerges the ugly significance of racial and ethnic animosities in
contemporary democratic politics. But it doesn’t really fit the facts.
In conventional
accounts, the global economic crisis triggered by the financial meltdown of
2008 was the key factor in what the author John Judis called “the populist
explosion.” As the journalist Matt O’Brien wrote in The Washington Post a
few months after Trump’s inauguration, “It shouldn’t be too surprising that the
worst economic crisis since the 1930s has led to the worst political crisis
within liberal democracies since the 1930s.” But it hasn’t. Although populist
parties in some places made electoral gains in the wake of the economic
calamity, they were mostly small and scattered. Moreover, careful survey
research showed that the supporters of populist parties were mostly
distinguished by traditional conservative ideology, as measured by where respondents
placed themselves on a left-to-right spectrum of political belief, and by
opposition to immigration and European integration; economic disaffection
played little discernible role.
But even that success
had less to do with the intrinsic appeal of right-wing populism than with the
“implosion” of the People’s Party, triggered by the failure of Prime Minister
Mariano Rajoy to head off a chaotic referendum on Catalan independence and the
convictions of several prominent party officials for their role in what the
High Court called an “authentic and efficient system of institutional
corruption.” In most of the places where populist parties have made significant
electoral gains, the explanations have been similarly prosaic; the scandals and
failures of mainstream parties were often paramount.
Economic disaffection
is similarly overblown as an explanation for the rise of Trump in the United
States. Pundits surmised that Trump’s rise was a testament to the crash of the
American middle class and the high debts and consequent frustration of millions
of Americans. But in their book-length analysis of the 2016 election, the
political scientists John Sides, Michael Tesler, and Lynn Vavreck found that
the biggest shifts in voting patterns were related to education, not income,
and that those shifts primarily reflected “attitudes about race and ethnicity,”
not “economic anxiety.” They concluded that “the dividing line between Clinton
and Trump voters was not the widespread belief that average Americans are being
left behind” economically. The real key was “how people explained economic
outcomes in the first place—and especially whether they believed that
hard-working white Americans were losing ground to less deserving minorities.”
A separate analysis by the political scientist Diana Mutz likewise showed that
perceived loss of status, not tangible economic deprivation, explained the 2016
presidential vote. Even so-called deaths of despair—such as suicides and deaths
caused by addiction and overdose—in economically devastated white working-class
communities seem not to have had the populist resonance that many pundits
imagined. Sides, Tesler, and Vavreck found that whites who voted for Clinton
were more likely than those who voted for Trump to report knowing someone who
had abused alcohol or been addicted to painkillers.
Build the Wall
Support for populist
parties and candidates in contemporary Western democracies is driven primarily
not by economic grievances but by cultural concerns. In broad terms, these
parties and candidates appeal to people distressed by the pace of social and cultural
change in Western societies. Like William F. Buckley’s conservatives in the
1950s, today’s right-wing populists stand athwart history yelling, “Stop!” In
the United States, changes stemming from the decades-long struggle for racial
justice and the decline of organized religion are major sources of distress for
this group. Fears about the erosion of local and national identities loom large
in many places. But the most concrete and common source of tension is
immigration—especially that of people ethnically and culturally distinct from
existing populations.
Many affluent
societies have experienced significant inflows of immigrants in recent decades.
The European refugee crisis that began in 2015 provided new opportunities for
right-wing populist entrepreneurs to stoke and exploit long-simmering concerns
about immigrants and immigration, inflaming public fears about “the great
replacement” of a white majority by nonwhites. As with the supposed impact of
the economic crisis, however, the causes and political implications of these
developments are often misunderstood.
At a rally organized by the Spanish far-right Vox
party, Madrid, May 2024
For one thing, there is
remarkably little relationship between the scale of immigration in specific
countries and the extent of anti-immigrant sentiment. In long-running
cross-national surveys, Germany and Sweden, which have experienced substantial
immigration, remain among the most welcoming countries in Europe; the refugee
crisis barely dented favorable opinions there toward immigrants and
immigration. Hungary and Poland, which have not received many immigrants
(although Poland has taken in many refugees from Ukraine), are among the most
hostile—largely because their governments have energetically scapegoated
immigrants, another instance of leaders manufacturing rather than responding to
public opinion.
The ubiquitous notion
that the immigration crisis was tearing Europe apart represented an
overreaction to the agitation of a xenophobic minority. Just as the press tends
to exaggerate electoral gains by anti-immigrant parties, it tends to mistake
outbursts by extremists for broad shifts in public opinion. Across Europe,
attitudes toward immigrants and immigration have become substantially more
favorable since the turn of the century, even in places where there have been
significant inflows of immigrants. This shift is largely due to generational
replacement, as younger, better-educated people are less concerned about
immigration than their parents and grandparents have been. In surveys conducted
in the past few years, the difference in attitudes toward immigrants and
immigration between young Europeans (born in the late 1990s) and some of the
oldest ones (born in the early 1930s) is comparable to the difference between
the countries that have the most favorable perceptions of immigration, such as
Norway and Sweden, and those that have the least favorable, such as Poland or
Slovenia. Although immigration is not about to disappear as a political issue,
it is swimming upstream against a strong generational current.
A similar
generational divide appears in the United States. Indeed, in recent years, the
long-standing gap in immigration attitudes between older and younger Americans
has widened. A 2023 Gallup poll found that 55 percent of people 55 and older
wanted the level of immigration reduced, but only 16 percent of
18-to-34-year-olds agreed.
For some older
Americans, especially, concerns about immigration have been supercharged by the
deeper fear of becoming strangers in their own country. A decade ago, the
psychologists Maureen Craig and Jennifer Richeson showed that reminding white
Americans of a projected demographic future in which whites are outnumbered by
nonwhites significantly altered their political attitudes. Now, such reminders
are constant, as politicians and pundits on the right incessantly hawk the
conspiratorial notion that radical elites are using nonwhite migration to
hasten that future and cement their own hold on power. For people who view
demographic diversity as a significant threat to the traditional American way
of life, the political stakes could hardly be higher.
The frictions
stemming from immigration are real. But they reflect the increasing intensity
of feeling among a minority, not the massive, irresistible tide of popular
conviction that many observers imagine. Moreover, their political implications
are often overblown; much of the opposition to immigration is more symbolic
than concrete. For example, a June 2024 Gallup poll found 47 percent of
Americans saying they favored “deporting all immigrants who are living in the
United States illegally back to their home country.” But anyone tempted to take
that dire finding at face value would do well to note that 70 percent of the
same survey respondents said they favored “allowing immigrants living in the
United States illegally the chance to become U.S. citizens if they meet certain
requirements over a period of time.” As with many issues, there may be less to
the public’s immigration policy preferences than meets the eye. Exaggerating
the breadth and solidity of anti-immigrant sentiment merely encourages mainstream
political leaders to cave to pressure from extremists, abdicating their
responsibility to craft policies and rhetoric that address the issue soberly
and sensibly.
Barking Dogs
The electoral
successes of populist parties invariably raise alarms about their potential
impact on public policy. But that impact, too, is often exaggerated and, even
more often, difficult to assess. Regardless of the specific institutional
structure in which they operate, populists generally need political allies to
shape policy. In majoritarian systems, that requires bargaining within parties
and governments. In multiparty systems, it usually requires populist parties to
partner with mainstream parties in governing coalitions. The more extreme a
populist party is, the less attractive it tends to be as a coalition partner
and the more likely it is to have to moderate its policy ambitions to
participate in government. Thus, as the political scientist Cas Mudde once put
it, even when western Europe’s right-wing populists reach parliament, they are
“dogs that bark loud, but hardly ever bite.”
The accession of the
right-wing populist Giorgia Meloni to the post of
prime minister of Italy in 2022 is a case in point. Meloni’s rise was portrayed
as the vanguard of yet another “new wave of populism,” but in truth, she
benefited from the crash of Matteo Salvini, an earlier far-right leader who
lost support after he overplayed his hand in a coalition government. As prime
minister, Meloni has been less zealous and ideological than many analysts
anticipated, constrained by Italy’s reliance on the European Union for economic
support and by her coalition partners.
In some countries,
mainstream political leaders have long shunned populist parties as political
allies. In Sweden, for example, the electoral rise of the right-wing
populist Sweden Democrats was counterbalanced for many years by mainstream
parties across the political spectrum refusing to partner with it in governing
coalitions, even at the cost of ceding power to their rivals. In 2018, the
Sweden Democrats’ 62 seats in parliament represented a clear balance of power
between the Red-Green coalition’s 144 seats and the center-right Alliance’s 143
seats. Nonetheless, the mainstream parties negotiated for more than four
months, eventually settling on a precarious but functional center-left
coalition. In 2022, the Sweden Democrats won 73 seats, making it the largest
party in a prospective center-right coalition. But the reluctance of the other
parties in the coalition to partner with it resulted in a minority government
with carefully negotiated external support from the Sweden Democrats. Although
the norm of “cordoning” the Sweden Democrats from power has clearly eroded in
recent years, it hasn’t disappeared. Whatever one may think about the
legitimacy of nullifying the influence on the government of a substantial
minority of voters, political leaders in multiparty systems retain considerable
leeway to do just that.
Orban and Meloni in Rome, June
The efforts of
mainstream political elites to contain the policy influence of right-wing
populists are similarly evident in the Netherlands, where the issue of
immigration fueled a major political crisis, leading to the collapse of the
longtime prime minister Mark Rutte’s center-right coalition in 2023. The big
winner in the resulting snap election, more than doubling its previous vote
share and parliamentary representation, was the Party for Freedom, helmed by
the anti-immigrant firebrand Geert Wilders. Although
some media declared the outcome “a tectonic change in the Dutch political
landscape,” Wilders’s potential coalition partners blocked him from becoming
prime minister, eventually settling on a new leader with no party ties or
political experience. As in Sweden, the policy impact of Wilders’s election
victory remains to be seen.
For mainstream
politicians, attempting to suppress populist parties and the grievances they
exploit may often be good politics. Yet it sometimes risks further alienating
their supporters. A survey conducted in the six months following Sweden’s 2018
election showed satisfaction with Swedish democracy declining substantially
among people who had reported voting for the Sweden Democrats, as the drawn-out
post-election maneuvering made it increasingly clear that the party would once
again be shut out of government. Managing the currents of populism sometimes
requires concessions and compromise. More often, however, political leaders
panicked by the overblown threat of a populist wave probably concede more than
they must or should. Perhaps the most consequential instance of such
overreaction was British Prime Minister David Cameron’s promise in 2013 to
stage a referendum on the United Kingdom’s membership in the European Union, a
reckless gamble intended to blunt the exaggerated threat of the UK Independence
Party and a move that even many who supported it soon came to regret.
Throw the Rascals Out
While observers have
overstated the electoral successes and political clout of populist parties,
they have also exaggerated what is at stake in those successes by conflating
populism with democratic backsliding. According to the political scientists Yascha Mounk and Roberto Stefan Foa, “Far-right populist parties . . . have risen from
obscurity to transform the party system of virtually every Western European
country. Meanwhile, parts of Central and Eastern Europe bear witness to the
institutional and ideological transformations that might be afoot: In Poland
and Hungary, populist strongmen have begun to put pressure on critical media,
to violate minority rights, and to undermine key institutions such as
independent courts.” The word “meanwhile” is doing a lot of work here. In fact,
the parties that eroded democratic institutions in Hungary and Poland bore
little resemblance to the populist parties of western Europe, and the forces
fueling their rise were largely unrelated to the conventional understanding of
right-wing populism.
In Hungary, Prime
Minister Viktor Orban’s Fidesz party came to
power in 2010 as the only viable alternative to an incumbent party fatally
discredited by years of scandal and mismanagement. Contrary to many observers’
assumptions, Fidesz’s support at that point was unrelated to anti-immigrant
sentiment, resistance to European integration, political distrust, and other
common bases of support for right-wing populist parties. Only after winning did
Orban turn to scapegoating refugees and the European Union, adapting and
extending the populist playbook and pulling the views of his supporters closer
to those of right-wing populists elsewhere. But the vote that brought Orban to
power in 2010 was a surprisingly routine instance of “throwing the rascals
out,” not a welling up of xenophobic or antidemocratic passions.
Having won 53 percent
of the popular vote—hardly a ringing mandate under the circumstances—Orban
exploited what one Hungarian writer aptly called an “accidental” two-thirds
majority in the National Assembly to retrospectively declare a transparently
bogus “voting booth revolution,” engineering changes to the electoral system
and constraints on civil servants and the media intended to entrench Fidesz in
power. This assault on Hungarian democracy was not a reflection of Hungarians’
yearning for populism, much less for authoritarianism. Orban took advantage—as
incumbent politicians in many times and places have—of an opportunity to
rewrite the rules of the game in his favor.
Orban’s changes
to the Hungarian electoral system and attacks on independent media gave Fidesz
“an undue advantage” in subsequent elections, as an international monitor
reported in 2014. An even more important basis for the party’s continued hold on
power, however, was a marked improvement in ordinary Hungarians’ subjective
quality of life. Surveys registered massive improvements after 2009 in public
satisfaction with the economy, the national government, and—ironically—the
working of Hungarian democracy. These improvements in subjective well-being
continued for several years after Fidesz’s rise to power.
Democratic
backsliding in Poland followed a similar course after the
center-right Law and Justice party’s victory in
2015. “Law and Justice won big,” a BBC News analyst explained at the time,
“because they offered simple, concrete policies,” including “higher child-care
benefits and tax breaks for the less well-off.” Scholars concurred that Law and
Justice “softened its image,” running on the anodyne slogan “Good Change.” Only
after taking power did the party turn to packing the judiciary with party
loyalists, castigating the European Union, and tightening its control over
state radio and television. “You have given an example,” the party leader
Jaroslaw Kaczynski told Orban in 2016, “and we are learning from your example.”
If the authoritarian
turn in Poland was attributable to political elites rather than ordinary citizens,
the same might be said of its end. The ouster of the Law and Justice party in
an election in October 2023—just a month after its expected reelection had been
touted in The Economist as part of “a fresh wave of hard-right
populism”—led some observers to wonder whether Europe’s populist wave had
finally crested. But the election outcome was hardly a sea change in Polish
public opinion. The Law and Justice party’s 35 percent of the vote was only
slightly lower than the 38 percent vote share that brought it to power in 2015.
The key difference was not in voters’ behavior but in the determination of the
various opposition parties’ leaders to subsume their differences in a coalition
government led by former Prime Minister Donald Tusk.
Ordinary People, Extraordinary Times
The tolerance of many
citizens in Hungary and Poland for what scholars have characterized
as “mildly authoritarian” regimes may strike democratic idealists as
blameworthy, but it should not be surprising. Ordinary people in most times and
places have cared more for their security, their finances, and the validation
of their social identities than they have for the upholding of democratic norms
and procedures. Summarizing her detailed study of full-blown breakdowns of
democracy in twentieth-century Europe and Latin America, Ordinary
People in Extraordinary Times, the political scientist Nancy Bermeo wrote
that “ordinary people generally were guilty of remaining passive when dictators
attempted to seize power.” Although they “generally did not polarize and
mobilize in support of dictatorship, they did not immediately mobilize in
defense of democracy either.”
A study published in
2020 tested how survey respondents’ willingness to support a hypothetical
political candidate was affected by informing them that the candidate had
violated some democratic norm (for example, advocating the prosecution of
unfriendly journalists or ignoring unfavorable court rulings). The authors
concluded that “only a small fraction of Americans prioritize democratic
principles in their electoral choices,” making public opinion a “strikingly
limited” check on undemocratic behavior by elected officials. Turks and
Venezuelans were similarly “reluctant to punish politicians for disregarding
democratic principles when doing so requires abandoning one’s favored party or
policies.”
Americans’ commitment
to democratic principles was put to a more concrete test in 2022, when scores
of Republican members of Congress who had supported or condoned Trump’s “stop
the steal” effort following the 2020 election stood for reelection. In contested
general elections, they did not fare significantly worse or better than their
counterparts who had bucked Trump—the electoral cost of “disregarding
democratic principles” was essentially zero. Moreover, in other respects they
were advantaged; for example, they were much less likely to lose Republican
primary elections or to retire from politics and more likely to seek higher
office.
It might be tempting
to interpret public indifference to violations of democratic norms as itself a
product of the “populist wave.” In fact, it is a long-standing feature of
democratic politics and not only in the cases of breakdown studied by Bermeo.
Six decades ago, the political scientist Herbert McClosky’s classic study of
“consensus and ideology in American politics” documented the shallow allegiance
of many ordinary Americans to the “rules of the game.” McClosky concluded that
members of “the active political minority” were “the major repositories of the
public conscience” and “the carriers of the [democratic] Creed.”
In McClosky’s postwar
era, elite support for democratic norms was bipartisan. That consensus was
facilitated by the fact that policy differences between the two parties were
modest by historical standards. (In 1950, the American Political Science
Association issued a public report titled Toward a More Responsible
Two-Party System that advocated for stronger, more distinct party platforms
and greater power to implement them.) In recent years, however, the rise of
hot-button issues such as civil rights, abortion, immigration, and national
identity have polarized the parties, raising the stakes of political
contestation. In response, political elites—especially Republicans—have
demonstrated a troubling willingness to violate democratic norms in pursuit of
partisan advantage. The increasingly unrestrained struggle for power among
elites, not populism, represents the greatest threat to democracy in the United
States and elsewhere.
Case studies of
democratic breakdowns around the world suggest that the most important bulwark
against autocratic backsliding from the top is uncompromising opposition from
prominent political allies. Orban’s constitutional coup in Hungary required
absolute party discipline, facilitated by his ironclad control over the Fidesz
party apparatus and candidate selection. Although Trump’s control of the
Republican Party has been less complete, it has increased considerably since
2016. When he floated the possibility of postponing the 2020 election,
Republican leaders in Congress promptly and publicly rejected the idea, and it
was quickly dropped. But after the election, when Trump’s allies hatched a plan
to derail the certification of electoral votes, Republican congressional
leaders were divided in their response. Two-thirds of House Republicans ended
up voting to decertify electoral votes, while only seven of 51 Senate
Republicans did so.
Since 2021, Trump has
bolstered his standing among the Republican rank and file, as demonstrated by
his cakewalk through the 2024 primaries. He has also significantly tightened
his grip on the party organization—for example, by installing allies and in-laws
in the leadership of the Republican National Committee. Many of the Republican
leaders who resisted his extremist tendencies have voluntarily or involuntarily
retired from politics and been replaced by newcomers who seem willing to give
Trump a freer hand. Even if he wins reelection, the institutional fragmentation
of power in the U.S. system will leave him well short of the ironclad control
that Orban enjoys in Hungary. Nonetheless, with an increasingly united
Republican Party and an increasingly compliant Supreme Court supporting him,
there is good reason to fear a further erosion of democratic norms.
Trump’s movement to “Make America Great Again” appeals to a deep fear
of diversity and social change. That sort of fear is commonplace in all
societies, and it has often roiled democratic politics. Yet the threat Trump
poses to American democracy has little to do with “populism.” It doesn’t come
from ordinary citizens immersed in “culture wars”—even from those who stormed
the Capitol on January 6. They were and are a sideshow. The real threat is from
the Republican officeholders who, hours later, supported Trump’s effort to
decertify the election outcome. It was not some rush of antidemocratic feeling
that threatened American democracy in those months; it was the machinations of
political elites determined to entrench themselves in power.
At its heart,
widespread misunderstanding of the contemporary populist threat rests on a
misunderstanding of the nature of democracy itself. An idealized folk theory of
democracy, as the political scientist Christopher Achen called it, encourages
journalists, scholars, and ordinary citizens to imagine that the moving force
behind major shifts in party systems and governing coalitions must be
correspondingly major shifts in public opinion. If populist parties are gaining
strength in parliaments, it must be because people are turning against
immigration, European integration, and established political institutions.
(They are not.) If democratic norms and institutions are eroding, it must be
because public support for democracy as a system of government has weakened.
(It hasn’t.)
As the eminent
political scientist E. E. Schattschneider observed several decades ago, this
sort of understanding of democratic politics is “essentially simplistic, based
on a tremendously exaggerated notion of the immediacy and urgency of the
connection of public opinion and events.” The fate of democracy lies in the
hands of politicians. It is they who choose to manage, mollify, ignore, or
inflame populist sentiment. It is a dangerous blunder to gullibly accept their
show of bowing to the ostensible will of the people. And when popular
grievances are used as a pretext for bad policy—or, even worse, as a pretext
for democratic backsliding—it is politicians, not the citizenry, who are
culpable.
For updates click hompage here