By Eric Vandenbroeck and
co-workers
‘Weapons have given
you independence. Laws will give you freedom.’ This pledge to his fellow countrymen
from Francisco Paula de Santander, a Colombian independence leader, is
inscribed above the doorway of the Palace of Justice in Bogota’s Plaza BolIvar, its paved main square. The inscription has an
unintentionally ironic ring to it — and not only because freedom and the rule
of law long proved elusive, in Colombia and throughout Latin America. The
current version of the palace, of blond stone blocks, dates only from the
1990s. The previous building was destroyed by fire after guerrillas from the nationalist
M-19 movement seized it in 1985, taking the Supreme Court hostage. The army,
deploying armoured cars, retook the palace after
hours of fighting; 95 people, including the Supreme Court justices, died in the
confrontation.1 Not far away from the palace are other reminders of the
violence that has intermittently dogged Colombia. Near the Congress building on
the Carrera Septima, the city’s main artery, a plaque marks the spot where
General Rafael Uribe, a Liberal leader of the civil war of 1899 to 1902 —
chronicled in Garcia Márquez’s One Hundred Years of Solitude — was assassinated
a decade after he had made peace with a Conservative government. Half a dozen
blocks to the north along the same avenue a similar plaque marks a still more
controversial assassination: Jorge Eliécer Gaitán, a
crowd-pulling populist Liberal who seemed assured of victory in Colombia’s 1950
presidential election, was shot at point-blank range by a lone assassin as he
left his lawyer’s office. His murder on 9 April 1948 triggered a yet bloodier
civil war, known simply as la violencia, which
claimed perhaps 180,000 lives. It is still debated today in Colombia whether
the killer acted alone or at the behest of the Conservative opposition.
Though falling short
of the abysmal standard set by many other parts of the world, notably Europe,
political violence has been all too commonplace in Latin America over the past
two centuries. In that regard, Colombia occupies a prominent role, though it is
unusual partly because armed conflict has continued into the twenty-first
century even as it has died away everywhere else in the region over the past
decade. Paradoxically, Colombia has another claim to exceptionalism — one for
which Santander and his followers can take much credit. The country has an
unusually long democratic tradition: with only one brief exception, it has
elected civilian governments since the 183os with suffrage arrangements that
compared favorably with much of Europe. That statement requires one or two
caveats. There were periodic civil wars, mainly between the Liberals and the
Conservatives. The murder of Gaitán plunged the country not just into la violencia but also into a short military dictatorship.
Civilian rule was restored under a power-sharing pact between the two main
parties. This lasted from 1958 to 1974; it brought stability but restricted
political competition. And the writ of government has never extended over the
whole of a huge and fragmented territory with poor internal communications.
Even so, Colombia, along with Costa Rica and Uruguay, stands out from the rest
of Latin America: in all three countries, authoritarian dictatorships have been
brief and rare. In much of the rest of the region, periods of civilian rule alternated
with dictatorship; in some countries authoritarian rule was the norm at least
until the 1980s.
As Santander’s
injunction makes plain, some of Latin America’s independence leaders of the
1820s wanted to lay the foundations of democratic government. So why has
democracy fared so poorly? This chapter will explore that question by surveying
the region’s history for the first century or so after independence. History
still hangs heavy in Latin America: it is the stuff of contemporary politics,
constantly invoked by Hugo Chavez or Mexico’s Zapatista movement or by
Argentina’s Peronists, recalled in street names and statues. As Enrique Krauze,
a Mexican historian, has said of his country, ‘the weight of the past has
sometimes been more present than the present itself. And a repetition of the
past has sometimes seemed to be the only foreseeable future.’2 That is
especially true in Mexico, but it also applies in many other Latin American
countries. It is hard to analyze the prospects for consolidating democracy
without regard to this history, to the lessons that Latin Americans draw from
it, and the institutions, political traditions and economic practices which it
has bequeathed to the region.
The revolt of the 13
British colonies against King George III firmly planted democracy and
enlightenment republicanism in the western hemisphere. Along with the writings
of the French philosophes and British economic liberalism, the political
example set by the founding fathers of the United States exercised a strong
intellectual appeal for many of the independence leaders in Latin America. It
would not be until the end of the nineteenth century, the age of Arielismo, that ‘anti-Americanism’ would take a firm hold
in the region. Yet several things would hold the newly independent Latin
American nations back, and impede them from following the United States on its
path of democracy and development. These included the nature of the
independence struggle itself, the socio-economic order bequeathed by Iberia,
geographical factors and consequent economic fragility.
By comparison with
the war of American Independence of 1776—82, the fight for independence in
Spanish America was longer, bloodier and more destructive. It differed, too, in
being triggered by events on the other side of the Atlantic. Napoleon
Bonaparte’s invasion of Iberia in 1807—8 and his overthrow of the Spanish
Bourbon monarchy created a power vacuum at the heart of the empire. In 1808, as
news of these developments reached first Caracas, and then Buenos Aires and
other colonial centers, Juntas were formed to exercise power. They proclaimed a
nominal loyalty to Fernando VII, who was a captive in a French chateau. But
discontent among the criollos, as American-born whites were known, had been
building for at least a generation. At the start of the nineteenth century,
criollos made up some 3.3 million of Spanish America’s total population of 16.9
million.3 They were outnumbered by 7.5 million Indians, 5.3 million mestizos
and 776,000 blacks. Many criollos formed part of an incipient middle class of
managers, lawyers and other professionals. Others formed part of the economic
aristocracy of Spanish America, the owners of the great haciendas and the mines
and the merchants and traders. But all of them were excluded from political
power.
During his reign from
1759 to 1788, Carlos III, Fernando’s grandfather, had made a vigorous effort to
halt his country’s long decline, and to reform its system of colonial rule.
These ‘Bourbon reforms’ were in part the result of new ways of thinking. The
rationalism of the French enlightenment had an important influence in Iberia.
It challenged — albeit moderately at first — the Catholic conservatism that had
held Spain and its colonies in its thrall since the Counter-Reformation. In
Spanish America, the reforms involved more open trade (but only between ports
within the empire, not with other countries), the weakening of the power of the
Church (the Jesuits were expelled, for example), and a modest opening to new
ideas. Above all, the reforms involved more efficient administration. But that
meant a tightening of the control of Madrid over local affairs — a ‘new
imperialism’ as John Lynch, a historian of the independence era, puts it.4 In
particular, the Bourbons restored a near-monopoly of political office in the
Americas to Spanish-born peninsulares (who numbered
no more than 40,000 in the empire as a whole around 1800). This applied not
just to the viceroys and other senior officials but to membership of the
audiencias or high courts: of 266 appointments to audiencias from 1751 to 1808,
only 62 were of criollos.5
These reforms had two
unintended effects. First, they helped to divide the rich and powerful in both
Spain and its colonies into liberal and conservative camps — a division that
would last in both places until at least the early twentieth century. In Spain
itself, liberalism first showed its hand when opponents of Napoleon convened in
Cádiz in i8io a parliament or Cortes — an institution with medieval origins but
which had been snuffed out by centuries of absolutism. A majority of the
members of the Cortes were reformers: they called themselves Liberals, the
first time anywhere that the word was used as a political identity.6 The Cortes
proceeded to declare itself sovereign and issue a constitution which called for
a parliamentary monarchy and widespread male suffrage. Second, in Spanish
America, the reforms rammed home to the criollos that they lacked the political
power to defend their economic privilege. That gave rise to grievance, over the
trade monopoly and taxes, for example. It also bred disquiet: some criollos
came to see Spanish weakness as being as big a threat to their interests as
Spanish power. They worried that a power vacuum at the top would threaten
social order and private property.
They were haunted by
a two-headed specter of popular rebellion. In 1791, inspired by the principles
of the French Revolution, the black slaves of the sugar island of
Saint-Domingue, France’s richest colony, revolted. ‘It was a terrifying
revelation of the explosive force of stifled savage hatred,’ as one account
puts it.7 In the first two months, 2,000 whites (or one in five) were killed,
i8o sugar plantations and 900 coffee and indigo farms were destroyed and ten
thousand slaves died in fighting, repression or famine. After a dozen
years of violence and warfare, in which they successively defeated armies sent
by Republican France, Spain, Britain and Napoleon, the former slaves triumphed,
and in 1804 Saint-Domingue became Haiti — the second independent nation in the
western hemisphere. But such was the destruction and the infighting among the
patriots that the victory was a Pyrrhic one.8
Ten years prior to
Haiti’s slave revolt, in the mountains south of Cusco, the former Inca capital,
an Andean Indian cacique (local boss) called José Gabriel Condorcanqui
had rebelled against the viceroy in Lima. He took the name of Tupac Amaru II,
after the last Inca. His demands were a vague mixture of opposition to the
Bourbon reforms, Inca revivalism and independence. After six months, he was
captured and, along with his wife Micaela Bastides, vas executed with great
cruelty in Cusco’s main square. His rebellion had extended over much of the
southern half of the viceroyalty of Peru, as far i
northern Argentina. Some one hundred thousand people died, and there was much
destruction of property.9 Although Condorcanqui
himself had stressed that his movement was a multi-ethnic one, many of his
Indian supporters had been quick to turn their ire on the whites.
The memory of these
events meant that many criollos, especially in Peru and Mexico with their large
Indian populations, did not at first favor cutting the link with Spain. Even
Simon Bolivar, the great Liberator of northern South America, worried about the
sheer numbers of the slaves and the mixed-bloocipardos
in his native Venezuela, stating: ‘A great volcano lies at our feet. Who shall
restrain the oppressed 10 Many historians have thus seen independence not as a
progressive revolution in the mould of that of
Washington and Jefferson, but rather as a conservative reaction. It was that—
but it was more than that. Motives and interests within Spanish America varied,
but the desire for the removal of colonial restraints was strong. It expressed
itself first in Venezuela and the River Plate region, in part because they were
the first to hear the tumultuous news from Spain and in part because as trading
colonies they had been hit hardest by the Bourbon reforms. In both places, the
criollos, invoking a Spanish tradition of communalism with strong medieval
roots, called a cabildo (town meeting), deposed the colonial authorities and
proclaimed a governing junta. In Caracas, independence was declared in 1811; in
the United Provinces of the River Plate, from which would emerge Argentina, the
declaration came five years later. In Mexico alone the cry for independence
came from below, from Miguel Hidalgo, a parish priest in the central Bajio region, who raised an Indian horde.
The struggle was
almost everywhere protracted and convoluted, taking on the character of a civil
war. The patriots were often divided, by local interest as much as by ideology.
Social disorder, or the fear of it, caused many criollos to hesitate before breaking
the bonds with Spain. The defeat of Napoleon saw Fernando restored to the
Spanish throne in 1814, able to dispatch reinforcements to America. An
expedition of ten thousand seasoned troops reached Venezuela in 1815, the
darkest period for the patriot cause across the region. These were partly
offset by the arrival of 6,000 mainly British and Irish volunteers who fought
as mercenaries with Bolivar’s armies. This force apart, Latin America lacked
the kind of external support that France had offered the Washington in the
United States.
Two things combined
finally to surprise South America from Spain’s grasp. The first was better
strategy and organization on the patriot side. In southern South America, José
de San Martin, an Argentine who had served for two decades as a regular officer
in the Spanish army before joining the patriotic cause, pulled off a bold
strategic move. He organized and led a force of five thousand troops across the
Andes to Chile, through snowy 4,000-metre-high passes, an surprised the Spanish
forces there. Having secured Chile, he embarked in the ships of Thomas
Cochrane, a swashbuckling British admiral who served the patriot cause as a
mercenary, and landed his army in Peru. He (temporarily) freed Lima, which
until the Bourbon reforms had been the capital of the whole of Spanish South
America and remained a royalist bastion. San Martin’s forces joined up with
those of Simon Bolivar. Bolivar himself had recovered from a rout in his native
Venezuela in 1812. By allying with the ilaneros
(cowboys) of the Venezuelan plains, and through indefatigable generalship,
including a march up and over the Andes to Bogota even more demanding than that
of San Martin, he had freed northern South America. Spain’s last redoubt in
Peru was surrounded and would fall to a multinational army under Bolivar. In
1826, the last remaining Spanish troops surrendered to his forces in Upper Peru
(soon to become Bolivia).
The second factor was
the twists and turns of peninsular politics, as power in Spain’s restored
monarchy oscillated between incipient parliamentary liberalism and absolutist
reaction. Spanish strategy was misguided as well as confused. The liberals
failed to seek compromises, such as home rule, until it was far too late.
Royalist repression was often self-defeating. The Spanish forces sequestered
the property of their opponents and, in Colombia for example, executed a number
of patriots. On the other hand, the advent of a liberal government in Spain
after 1820 prompted the conservative criollos of Mexico to opt for
independence. The disorderly Indian armies led by Hidalgo and another radical
priest, José Miguel Morelos, had rampaged across half the country to the alarm
of the criollos, before being defeated and their leaders killed. In 1821,
Agustin Iturbide, a criollo general who had fought for Spain, made common cause
with the remaining rebel leaders, proclaimed independence and ruled briefly as
emperor of Mexico.
Only in Brazil was
independence a less-than-traumatic affair. When Napoleon invaded Iberia,
Britain arranged to ship the Portuguese monarch and his court across the
Atlantic to Rio de Janeiro. It was the only occasion the history of European
empire in which a colony became the metropolis. The result was that it was the
Portuguese monarchy that provided Brazil with almost all of the founding
institutions, usually the task of a postcolonial government: a centralized
administration and bureaucracy; superior law courts; a public library and an
academy of fine arts; a school of medicine and law; a national press and
national bank; and a military academy.’1 After hostilities ceased in Europe,
King Joao VI returned, with some tardiness, to Lisbon. As the Cortes in
Portugal attempted to reassert colonial control, Joao’s Jest son, left behind
as regent, quickly realized that the price of maintaining monarchy in Brazil
was independence. He declared it in 1822 and ruled as Dom Pedro I. Though war
with Portugal followed, it was brief and mainly ::led at sea by the skill of
Cochrane.’2
The armies involved in the independence wars were not large: Bolivar never more
than ten t men into battle. But in some places almost two decades of
near-continuous fighting wreaked a heavy toll. Mines had been flooded, farms
looted and bridges destroyed. In 1821, the coin produced by the mint in Mexico
City from the country’s silver mines totaled just 6 million pesos, down from
million pesos a year before the wars.13 Recovery would take decades. With
elegance but perhaps some exaggeration, Felipe Fernández-Armesto, an Anglo-
Spanish historian, has recently summarized the comparative impact:
the independence wars were, in short, the making of the United States and the
ruin of much of the rest of the Americas ... To fight the wars, all the
affected (Spanish-American) states had to sacrifice liberties to caudillismo
and civil values to militarism ... People in the Americas often speak of the
chaotic politics, democratic immaturity, and economic torpor of Latin American
tradition as if they were an atavistic curse, a genetic defect, a Latin legacy.
Really, like everything else in history, they are products of circumstance, and
of the circumstances, in particular, in which independence was won.14
The colonial inheritance
Apart from its costly
birth, the second handicap faced by newly independent Latin America was the
legacy of the Iberian colonial order, which made ill equipped for democracy and
development. Colonial Latin America differed radically from New England or Canada
(though less so from the more southerly of Britain’s American colonies). In the
sixteenth century, the conquistadores had brought with them a kind of
militarized feudalism. This had been honed in the reconquista,
the seven centuries of intermittent war that had driven the Moors from Spain.
In 1492, in one of history’s more striking coincidences of date, Columbus made
his first landfall in the ‘new world’ just as the Muslim emirate of Granada,
the last Moorish foothold Iberia, was overrun, completing the reconquista. The Spanish took two other sixteenth-century
philosophies across the Atlantic. One was a militant, intolerant Catholicism,
derived partly from the reconquista but given more
force by the Counter-Reformation with its Inquisition and apparatus of
censorship. The Spanish crown tried to control who settled in the Americas
indeed it went so far as to obtain a papal bull to uphold its authority to so.
In sharp contrast with English-speaking North America, no heretics, dissidents
or freethinkers needed to apply. The second guiding philosophy was
mercantilism. This doctrine held that gold and silver bullion was the ultimate
source of wealth — and not merely another commodity — and that trade was a
zero-sum game. So Spain imposed a rigid monopoly of trade with its colonies,
and discouraged the production of items that might compete with its own farmers
and artisans. The backbone of the colonial economy became the hacienda (the
large landed estate with resident serfs), the plantation and the mine. The crown
had swiftly imposed central authority on the con quistadores.
The principal institution of government was the audiencia, a judicial body but
one which was presided over by the king’s representative — the viceroy or
captain general — whom it also advised. Though there were also cabildos (town
councils) their responsibilities were mior. The crown
issued a constant flow of decrees — over 400,000 by 1635, though they were
later codified into 6,400.15 Almost from the start, the crown relied on the
sale of offices to raise revenue. Several familiar characteristics of Latin
American government thus date from the colonial period: centralisation
and the blurring of executive and judicial authority.16 To this list one might
add a regulatory mania. Legislation in Latin America often embodies an ideal
world, impossible to carry out in practice. That gave rise to a famous response
among colonial officials: obedezco pero no cumplo (I obey but I do
not comply). The result was less the rule of law than the realm of discretion,
giving rise to corruption and politically influenced justice.17
Unlike the Pilgrim
Fathers (and the Portuguese in Brazil), the Spaniards conquered territories
with large populations of native Americans. In Mexico’s central plateau, in
Guatemala and in Peru, these had formed sophisticated and wealthy societies
based on sedentary farming. At the time of their respective European conquests,
Latin America may have contained some 20 million people, compared with some 3
million spread across what would become Canada and the United States. Millions
of native Americans died, above all from disease but also from forced labor and
conquest itself. But one of the enduring differences between the two Americas
is that many more Indians survived in Latin America. The Spaniards quickly
realized that they needed Indian labor. Colonial Spanish America became a caste
society: a small group of large landowners, officials and clergy ruled over a
much larger population of Indians. Spanish absolutism recognized some rights
(known as fueros) for its subjects, but these were exercised by groups, not
individuals. The Church, the army and militia, some professions and the Indians
had their own fueros. Indeed, the Spaniards found it convenient to administer
the Indian population through curacas or caciques,
local Indian leaders, many of whose privileges were left intact (this
arrangement came : be known as the Reptthlica de
Indios). Many of their charges suffered servitude in mines and haciendas.
Others continued to live in traditional communities, whose lands were given
some legal protection. But they paid tribute to their new overlords.
This arrangement was
basically stable. Pre-conquest Indian societies were themselves rigidly
hierarchical: the Indians thus swapped a local master for a European one —
although the Incas, in particular, had been more paternalist rulers than the
Spaniards. The conquest had involved the brutal imposition of a new ideological
order as well as a political and economic one. In Mexico City recent excavation
has revealed how the Spaniards built their cathedral on top of part of the
Aztec Templo Mayor; in Cusco, a Dominican monastery stands on top of the Koricancha (the temple of the sun), the holiest shrine of
the Inca empire. The Indian gods had failed, and those of the con quistadores had triumphed. No wonder that the Indians would
embrace the Catholic religion while seeking to infuse it with their own
practices, beliefs and images (such as Mexico’s Virgin of Guadalupe). No
wonder, too, that some of Latin America’s Indian peoples to this day remain
suspicious of change and modernization. Their history since the conquest has
been one of enforced submission, followed by more or less successful adaptation
punctuated by occasional outbursts of rebellion, often of great violence. In
places where the Indian population was wiped out (Cuba, Hispaniola), or where
Indians were relatively few, nomadic and difficult to subjugate (Brazil), the
colonists turned to the mass import of African slaves instead.
Inequality was a
fundamental and integral aspect of colonial societies, whether they were based
on serfdom or slavery or both. ‘Perhaps nowhere is inequality more shocking,’
noted Alexander von Humboldt, an aristocratic German scientist and traveler, in
his essay on New Spain (Mexico) published in i8n. ‘The architecture of public
and private buildings, the women’s elegant wardrobes, the high society
atmosphere: all testify to an extreme social polish which is in extraordinary
contrast to the nakedness, ignorance and coarseness of the 18 Spanish colonial
theory did not entertain the idea of racial integration. It envisaged racial
separation, partly in order to protect the Indian population from the criollos.
Spaniards, criollos and Indians lived under separate laws. Yet over the
centuries much racial mixing occurred. Men always greatly outnumbered women
among Iberian colonists, and overwhelmingly so at the start. Miscegenation
resulted in a large number of mestizos and mulatos,
pardos and zambos. In that sense, Spanish colonial society was more fluid than
that of British North America (and Portuguese Brazil even more so). The
colonial period saw ‘the incomplete development of a heterogeneous hispanic-indigenous-mestizo -criollo society, which to this
day exists in ferment’, in the words of Jorge Basadre,
Peru’s greatest historian.19 This was even more the case in Mexico.
Even so, the
underlying socio-economic divides, broadly speaking, ran along racial lines.
The fears, resentments and ignorance which racial difference
generated made that divide all the harder to break down. At the heart of the
history of Latin America since independence has been the tension between the
beneficiaries of that divide and the gathering forces of socio-political
mestizaje.
While Brazil remained
intact, by 1830 mainland Spanish America had fragmented into 15 separate
countries.20 Given its size, this was inevitable. The new republics extended
over an area stretching from the borders of Oregon and Oklahoma to the stony
desert of Patagonia. But while some of the new countries, such as those in
Central America, looked too small to be viable, others were too big and
unwieldy quickly to become coherent nation-states. The most obvious example was
Mexico. It would lose half its original territory, as first Texas declared
itself independent and then the United States waged a successful war of
conquest (1846—8), seizing northern Mexico in the name of its ‘manifest
destiny’ to occupy the North American continent.21 Meanwhile, Yucatan was for
practical purposes all but independent during the first half of the nineteenth
century. In 1849, it asked to be annexed by the United States, but was turned
down. It had no road or rail link with Mexico City until as late as the 1950s.
Until then, its ties with New Orleans and Havana, via steamer services, were
closer than those with the Mexican capital.
Geography placed huge
obstacles in the way of development. Distances are vast: Brazil is as large in
area as the continental United States, while Argentina (with 37 million people
today) is almost as big as India (with 1 billion). The Andes are a formidable
barrier to communication, as is the Amazon basin. Most of the more populated
parts of Latin America lack navigable rivers. There are no significant ones on
the Pacific Coast at all. In South America, three mighty river systems — the
Amazon, the Paraná and the Orinoco — traverse the continent from the Andean
watershed to the Atlantic. Only in the past decade have the Paraná-Paraguay and
stretches of the Amazon been turned into reliable waterways for the transport
of bulk cargoes.22 In the high altitudes of the Andes, life is harsh.23 To
survive, farmers must exploit microclimates at varying altitudes as well as
grappling with erratic rainfall. To do so demands a high degree of collective
organization — a world away from the family homestead of bucolic New England.
Tropical lowlands pose a different set of challenges, including disease,
flooding and hurricanes. While some parts of Latin America get little or no
rain, others get far too much: some 70 per cent of Mexico’s total annual
average rainfall lands on the state of Tabasco, for example. To cap it all,
earthquakes are relatively common along the region’s western mountain spine,
and so are volcanic eruptions. Mexico, Central America and the Caribbean suffer
frequent hurricanes.
Yet Latin America
also possesses geographical advantages. These include abundant natural
resources, and much good land. The Pampas of Argentina, Uruguay and southern
Brazil form some of the world’s most fertile farmland, blessed with a temperate
climate. For much of the nineteenth century, land was abundant in relation to
population (which is variously estimated to have totaled only 15 to 20 million
at independence). But transport difficulties only began to be eased by the
coming of railways in the second half of the nineteenth century, and later by
air transport, which flourished as early as the 1920S in countries such as
Brazil and Colombia. Contrary to nationalist myth, the railways did much to
develop the domestic economy, as well as exports. In southern Brazil, for
example, railways gave a big boost to commercial farming aimed at supplying the
growing cities.24 Even so, in the larger countries communications between the
capital and outlying areas often remained poor until the mid-twentieth century.
This stimulated regional political movements and engendered persistent localism
as well as impeding internal trade. ‘Its own extent is the evil from which the
Argentine Republic suffers ... wastes containing no human dwelling, are,
generally speaking, the unmistakable boundaries between its several provinces,’
complained Domingo Faustino Sarmiento, later president of Argentina, in
Facundo, his mid-nineteenth- century tract against the evils of caudillismo.25
Caudillos and Modernizers
Spain’s monopoly of
trade and high political office during the colonial period meant that the new
republics had no experience of self-government, as BolIvar
bitterly complained. It would take many of them half a century or more to
achieve a degree of stability. Intermittent internal conflict added to the
damage inflicted by the independence war. When they were not merely struggles
for local or national power, these battles were over how the new republics
should governed — and by and for whom. Early efforts to establish a degree of
popular sovereignty failed almost everywhere. Most of the new republics lapsed
into three decades or more of rule by caudillos or strongmen, most of them army
officers of the independence campaigns. Some were enlightened; many were not.
For different reasons,
many writers on Latin America of both left and right have stressed the
continuities rather than changes associated with independence. Rule by a small
‘white’ elite and the basic inequalities of colonial society were preserved. In
some ways they were aggravated: the liberal commitment to private property
weakened some of the legal protections for Indian communal land. In many
countries, that would allow some degree of land-grabbing by hacendados
throughout the rest of the nineteenth century.
Together with mine
owners and large-scale traders, the landowners would form an oligarchy, holding
political as well as economic power. Yet to stop there is misleading. The
removal of the Spanish monopolies on political office, trade and the economy
did usher in a new order, but they did so gradually and by no means smoothly.
Overall, ‘Latin America was a far more egalitarian place after independence
than before. Indians and mestizos rose to positions of power all over Spanish
America,’ in the words of David Bushnell and Neill Macaulay, two historians of
the nineteenth century in the region.26 The newly independent countries all
adopted constitutions based, broadly speaking, on liberal principles. This in
itself was notable, given that most of Europe was still in the sway of
absolutism. The constitutions were heavily influenced by that of the United
States, by its Bill of Rights and the Declaration of the Rights of Man of the
French revolution. Though suffrage was limited by property qualifications,
usually to only a small percentage of adult males, so it was in Britain and the
United States in this period.
In Brazil, Dom Pedro
I established a liberal constitutional monarchy which included elements of
representative parliamentary government. This involved indirect elections —
deputies were picked by provincial electors, and senators chosen by the
emperor. Suffrage was relatively wide for the times, with some ii per cent of
the total population able to vote for the provincial electors in 1872.27
According to a recent study by Bolivar Lamounier, a Brazilian political
scientist, the grafting of this representative element onto the remnants of
Portuguese absolutism was essential to maintain government control over such a
large country, raven with bloody local rebellions in the first thirty years
after independence.28 Under the first emperor’s long-reigning and Brazilian-
born son, Dom Pedro 11(1831—89), this incipient parliamentary system worked
well for several decades. In the view of Thomas Skidmore, a scholar of Brazil,
it offered a political environment comparable to that of Victorian Britain in a
much poorer and less developed country.29 The emperor was a fair and honest
ruler, an urbane and learned man who took the trouble to learn Guarani, the
most widely spoken indigenous language. But the last two decades of his rule,
following war with Paraguay which he pursued implacably, were marked by
political stagnation. In 1868 Dom Pedro dismissed a Liberal administration,
replacing it with a Conservative one. Thereafter, the emperor increasingly
became a hostage to advisers who were bent on delaying change — and the abolition
of slavery in particular — for as long as possible. This doomed Latin America’s
only experiment with monarchy. But the Brazilian empire’s notable achievements
had been to keep the vast country united — it was potentially as fissiparous as
Spanish America — and to implant a representative tradition.
In the new
Spanish-speaking republics, as in Brazil, the basic political split was between
liberals, like Santander, who wanted to move swiftly to dismantle the colonial
order, and conservatives, such as Bolivar became, who were worried about
instability and disorder (‘governability’, one might say). Across the region,
the role of the Church became a battleground. It was seen by liberals as a
reactionary bastion and as an obstacle to new ways of thinking and by
conservatives as a powerful force for social order. Another divide was over
federalism: liberals tended to favor decentralization, though not always.
Argentina was an exception: there federalism was seen as a way of recognizing
regional differences, and of neutralizing the overweening economic power of
Buenos Aires, home of liberalism and jealous monopolizer
of lucrative customs revenues. Looked at through another optic, liberals were
standard- bearers of modernization and of French and British enlightenment
thought, while conservatives defended a paternalist social order derived from
Church and colony. Such divisions cut across class: artisans and Indians were
as likely to support conservatives as liberals, partly because liberals tended
to oppose communal ownership of land and to favor lower tariffs on imports.
This division is an enduring one. It is reflected in part in two archetypal
figures in Latin American politics: the caudillo and what one might call the
modernizing technocrat. The modernizers were not always liberals, though they
often were, while the caudillos were characteristically, but not necessarily,
conservatives, and some (though by no means all) were social paternalists.
Many elements of both
these archetypal figures were awkwardly united in the person of Simon Bolivar.
He was ‘an exceptionally complex man, a liberator who scorned liberalism, a
soldier who disparaged militarism, a republican who admired monarchy,’ as John
Lynch put it in a recent biography.30 Bolivar was a cultivated man. He had
spent several years in Europe — he famously (and perhaps apocryphally) swore to
liberate South America while visiting Rome with his tutor and friend, Simon
Rodriguez. While on campaign, his aides lugged around a large trunk of books:
Voltaire and Montesquieu were among his favorite reading, but the trunk also
included Locke and Bentham.31 He was a great correspondent, and wrote with
clarity and vigor. He admired the systems of government of both the United
States and Britain, the most democratic of the day. He found slavery abhorrent.
He argued passionately for co-operation among the new republics, and is rightly
invoked today as a precursor of Latin American integration. He attempted to
maintain Venezuela, Nueva Granada (present-day Colombia) and Ecuador united as
a single country, Gran Colombia. And yet his chief political legacy is a
yearning for strong government and paternalist authoritarianism. He was
insistent that without a strong central authority the new republics would fall
apart. Though he subscribed to Montesquieu’s doctrine of the separation of
powers, what he most liked about the French philosopher was his insistence that
laws and institutions should be adapted to a country’s geography and culture.
From Rousseau he took the idea that it is the role of the leader to interpret
and represent ‘the general will’. In other words, strong and effective
leadership is self-legitimating and when necessary should override institutions
that guarantee individual liberty. Thus, much as Bolivar admired the United
States, he once said that he would rather see the Latin American republics
adopt the Koran than US federalism, which was ‘too perfect’. In South America
‘events ... have demonstrated that perfectly representative institutions are
not appropriate to our character, our customs, and our current level of
knowledge and experience’, he wrote in 1815.32
The definitive
statement of Bolivar’s political thought came a decade later, when he was asked
to write a constitution for a new republic which had taken his name: Bolivia.
This document had some features of liberal democracy: nominally at least, the
executive, legislature and judiciary were to be separated, and were to be
complemented by a fourth ‘moral’ power, a ‘chamber of censors’ with a
scrutinizing function. But Bolivar also included a hereditary senate and a
president for life, who would have far-reaching emergency powers and the right
to name his successor. This is constitutional monarchy in all but name. This
document was swiftly discarded by Bolivia. In 1828, Bolivar assumed the
dictatorship of Gran Colombia. He proceeded to undo some of the liberal reforms
introduced during his long absence campaigning in Peru by Santander, his
vice-president from whom he had become estranged. Bolivar restored the Indian
tribute and the privileges of the Church and banned the works of Bentham.
Despite his own views on the matter, he never tried to force through a ban on
slavery. After Gran Colombia split into its three constituent parts in 1830,
Santander, a pragmatic liberal, was elected as president of Colombia and is the
founder of its democratic tradition. But he is long forgotten outside his own
country. It is the great Liberator who still casts a shadow today.
Bolivar was not
himself a caudillo: he always sought to institutionalize authority.33 But his
name has long been invoked and misused by authoritarian rulers of far less
noble qualities, and far less sense. Venezuelan dictators, starting in the late
nineteenth century, found it expedient to establish an official cult of
Bolivar. His remains were repatriated in 1842, and in 1876 placed in a giant
casket which rests in the national Pantheon, a former church a few blocks up
the hill from his birthplace in the centre of
Caracas. The latest exponent of the cult is Hugo Chavez, who claims to be
implementing a ‘Bolivarian Revolution’ in Venezuela. Chavez included some
elements from the Bolivian constitution (such as the ‘moral power’) in
Venezuela’s charter of 2001. He shows a Bolivarian disregard for checks on
executive power. Although he has not dispensed with elections, Chavez shows
every sign of wanting to be president for life.34 But there is no reason to
believe that Bolivar, the patrician aristocrat, the instinctive liberal turned
pragmatic conservative who admired British parliamentary monarchy, the man who
tried to sell his mines to British investors, would have felt represented by
Chavez’s militarist populism. This, Lynch observes tartly, is a ‘modern perversion
of the cult’ which distorts Bolivar’s ideas; at least past dictators ‘more or
less respected the basic thought of the Liberator, even when they
misrepresented its meaning.’35
Where Bolivar was
arguably too deferential to what he saw as Latin American weaknesses, the
modernizing technocrats paid insufficient heed to local realities. They wanted
to make the new republics in the image of Europe or the United States. One of
the first to try to do so was Bernardino Rivadavia in
the province of Buenos Aires, the most important of the (still dis-)United
Provinces of the Rio de la Plata, the forerunner of Argentina. Rivadavia, a merchant and lawyer, was an admirer of Jeremy
Bentham’s utilitarianism. He dominated Argentine politics for much of the
1820s, first as chief minister and then as president of Buenos Aires province.
He and his supporters founded the University of Buenos Aires and other
educational establishments, endowing them with a scientific bias absent from
Spain’s scholastic educational tradition. He promoted the theatre and other
cultural enterprises. Rivadavia abolished the
ecclesiastical and military fueros, restricted Church landholdings, transferred
some Church welfare activities to a state- sponsored body, established freedom
of worship, and cut the size of the army. He signed a trade treaty with Great
Britain. In a debate that echoes to this day, his critics then and since blamed
the problems of the textile and wine producers of the interior on Rivadavia’s commitment to free trade. But the problems of
these incipient local industries had more to do with inefficiency and distance
from markets than with imports. When Juan Manuel de Rosas, a dictator,
increased tariffs in 1835 the response of local industries was ‘slow and
feeble’.36 From 1870 onwards, policies of Rivadavian
inspiration aimed at promoting trade, foreign investment and European
immigration would eventually see Argentina become one of the richest countries
in the world. Less happily, Rivadavia’s government
contracted a loan from Britain, spent it on war with Brazil over Uruguay, and
quickly defaulted. His liberalism was tinged with elitism. He tried to control
wages, rather than leaving them to the market. And he handed out the best lands
of the Pampas on long leases which in practice became grants. Intended to
create a middle class of farmers, the measure had the opposite effect: by 1830,
just 538 beneficiaries had received a total of o million acres of some of the
world’s best farmland. Rivadavia drew up a
constitution that would have given Argentina a strong central government —
something that conservative federalists in Buenos Aires province, and
especially beyond it, were not prepared to accept. In 1827, he headed into
exile — like so many subsequent would-be reformers.
The Rivadavians failed partly because they had little
understanding of the difficulties of the Argentine interior, and partly because
they were simply ahead of their time. Across many of the Spanish-speaking
republics, the Liberals’ day would not dawn again until after the 1848
revolution in Europe, which had almost as great an impact in Latin America as
in the old continent. In the following three decades, the Liberals — and by now
they called themselves thus — would return to power in mariy
countries and carry through much of the unfinished business of independence.
They laid the basis for republics based on civilian democratic politics and
popular sovereignty, even if much of the population was still excluded. In many
countries, slavery and the Indian tribute were finally abolished along with the
fueros of the Church and the army. Elected civilian presidents began to replace
the caudillos, although the vote was generally restricted to adult men and
subject to property and literacy qualifications.37
This new flowering of
liberalism in the third quarter of the nineteenth century was generally
pragmatic and reformist. It coincided with, and was strengthened by, the
emergence of Latin America from its post-independence economic torpor.
Innovations in transport and communications begat a first age of globalization,
in which the region enjoyed sustained export-led growth as a supplier of
commodities to the industrial world. Coffee transformed the economies of
Brazil, Colombia, Venezuela and Central America; grain, meat and wool did the
same for Argentina and Uruguay; oil for Mexico and Venezuela; mining for Chile,
Peru, Bolivia and Mexico; and sugar for Cuba, Mexico and Peru. A new urban
middle class, of merchants, lawyers and doctors, arose, which though still
numerically small was socially significant.
In Mexico, where the
mark of church and colony went deeper than almost anywhere else, the Liberal
triumph was heavily contested. In the wake of military defeat by the United
States in the war of 1846—8, Benito Juárez, a Zapotec Indian from Oaxaca, beat
Bolivia’s Evo Morales to the title of Latin America’s first elected president
of indigenous descent by more than 150 years. Juárez’s Liberals abolished the
military and Church fueros, and banned the Church from owning property. Their
Conservative opponents made the fatal mistake of appealing for outside help:
France’s Louis Napoleon responded by installing Maximilian, a Habsburg prince
and his distant relative, as emperor. The Liberals won the resulting civil war,
and the hapless Habsburg perished by firing squad.
Even in Peru, where
military men had been politically dominant, in 1872 Manuel Pardo, a young
businessman, was elected as the country’s first-ever civilian president, at the
head of a promising Civil Party. His election marked the triumph of a new
generation of Liberals, exemplified by Francisco Laso,
a painter and writer. In a country that had preserved much of the caste society
of the colonial period, Laso challenged racial
exclusion. His painting The Three Races or Equality before the Law, which today
hangs in Lima’s Museum of Art, shows a rich young white boy playing cards with
two girls, one black, the other Indian. The girls are presumably servants.
Cards in hand, they watch with quiet resignation. But the message of the
picture is that they are all equal players of the game. Pardo cut the military
down to size, reformed taxes and began to give Peru the rudiments of a modern
state. But much of this progress was undone when Chile declared war on Peru and
Bolivia in a scramble for the nitrates of the Atacama. Chile won partly because
it had British support but mainly because it was a better-organized state. That
achievement was the legacy of Diego Portales, a conservative who, like Bolivar,
favored strong government. Portales was a minister, but never sought the
presidency: he believed in the rule of law rather than of individuals. In the
183os he laid the foundations of a stable political system. In Chile, too, the
Liberals gained the ascendant by the 187Os.
The Liberals did not
hold sway everywhere. In Colombia, Conservative governments held power from
1885 until 1930. Venezuela and several Central American countries remained in
the grip of dictators, although several of these claimed allegiance to liberalism.
In many countries, caudillos survived as local strongmen. Much as some Liberals
regretted this, they could not be wished away. The caudillos embodied ‘the will
of the popular masses, the choice of the people’; they were the ‘natural
representatives’ of the ‘pastoral classes’, according to Juan Bautista Alberdi,
the pragmatic architect of Argentina’s 1853 constitution (which remains largely
in force today).38 Although this constitution gave the federal government the
power to intervene in the affairs of the provinces in exceptional
circumstances, the long-term price of Argentine unity and internal peace was to
allow the caudillos to preserve their fiefdoms in the poorer provinces of the
interior. That price would prove to be a heavy one. Much the same went for
several other countries.
The Liberal era
lasted, broadly speaking, from the mid-nineteenth century until 1930. For all
its limitations, the Liberal order represented important progress. In many
countries, relatively enlightened civilian governments made efforts to tackle
Latin America’s huge deficit in education and transport infrastructure. Even
so, in 1900 three-quarters of the 70 million Latin Americans still lived in the
countryside, three-quarters were illiterate and average life expectancy was
only forty years.39 Shaky as they were, from these foundations there was
certainly a chance that Latin America might have gone on to create genuine
democracies and sustained development. Yet three things were to conspire to
frustrate that chance. First, before it could consolidate its triumph, Latin
American liberalism mutated into a new and more authoritarian political
philosophy: positivism. Second, Latin America’s underlying inequalities meant
that the benefits of economic growth did not reach much of the population. And
third, from the outbreak of the First World War, the world economy entered upon
three decades of turbulence, while economic development and incipient
industrialization in the Latin American countries brought new social tensions.
In the history of
political ideas in Europe, positivism is little more than a footnote. In parts
of Latin America, it looms large. It is derived chiefly from Auguste Comte, a French social theorist of the early nineteenth
century. He saw the key to progress as lying in order and ‘scientific
development’, to be implemented by an enlightened intellectual elite. This
would be echoed in Rodó’s elitist ‘regeneration’. And
it suited the privileged groups of Latin America admirably, seeming as it did
to justify restrictions on popular sovereignty. Positivism did promote
industrial development, foreign investment, and reforms, for example, of education.
But like Bolivar’s thinking, it was another version of enlightened despotism
and provided a new justification for authoritarianism. Not for the last time in
Latin America, economic and political liberalism were divorced, as modernizing
technocrats were happy to serve Conservative dictators who gave them a free
rein in economic policy. Like General Augusto Pinochet, Chile’s dictator, or
Alberto Fujimori, Peru’s ruler from 1990 to 2000, the positivists championed
economic freedom but not political freedom.
When linked to the
social Darwinism of Herbert Spencer, positivism seemed to provide a scientific
justification for inequality — and indeed for racism.40 In the late nineteenth
century, conventional wisdom among educated Latin Americans was that the region’s
Indian and black peoples were a brake on progress. One consequence was the
promotion of immigration from Europe, though there were other, more powerful
motives for that:
South America in
particular was sparsely populated. Between 188o and 1915, Argentina received
4.2 million immigrants (chiefly from Spain and Italy) and Brazil 2.9 million
(mainly from Italy and Eastern Europe). Though this represented only 23 per
cent of the 31 million migrants who crossed the Atlantic in this period (70 per
cent went to the United States), it was a significant number for the receiving
countries. In 1914, around 30 per cent of Argentina’s population was
foreign-born, a much higher percentage than in the United States.41
Positivism was
especially influential in the two largest countries in Latin America. In Mexico
it buttressed ideologically the long dictatorship of Porflrio
Diaz (1884—1914), who had first been elected in 1876 as a liberal. A tough and
shrewd mestizo, from Oaxaca like Juárez for whom he had fought against the
French, DIaz gave Mexico its first period of
stability since the viceroyalty. During the ‘Porfiriato’,
a team of modernising technocrats known as the cientificos (scientists) proceeded to lay the foundations
of a modern economy and railway system. Diaz respected constitutional forms,
duly having himself elected president every four years. But in the words of a
contemporary observer, he had ‘demolished the apparatus of government and
concentrated all the subdivided power into his own hands’. Another
contemporary, Justo Sierra, an educationalist, gave Diaz a friendly warning:
‘There are no institutions in the Republic of Mexico — there is a man.’42 Diaz
visited terrible repression on Indians, in the far north-west and the
south-east, who stood in the way of progress. Social conditions remained grim:
in 1900 one child in two died in the first year of life, while 84 per cent of
Mexicans were illiterate.43
In Brazil, positivism
inspired the very creation of the republic. As Dom Pedro II clung to his
coterie of conservative landholding advisers, agitation against slavery
increasingly took on republican tones under the aegis of a group of positivist
lawyers and writers. Their leader, Benjamin Constant, lectured in the military
academy, and influenced a generation of army officers.44 When Dom Pedro finally
yielded and agreed to abolition in i888, it was too late. His action alienated
conservatives from the monarchy while coming far too late satisfy liberal
elements in the growing cities. Within months, a bloodless military coup
ushered in a republic. Brazil adopted a new flag emblazoned with the positivist
slogan ‘Order and Progress’. Though the new republic was nominally a civilian
democracy, it was a disappointingly elitist affair, dominated by the newly rich
coffee barons of the two most prosperous states, São Paulo and Minas Gerais.
Though voting became direct, suffrage was more restricted than under the empire.
At local level, positivists dispensed with many of the trappings of democracy.
State governors gave unconditional support to the federal president; in return,
their local Republican parties were given a free hand. Two positivists, Julio
de Castilhos and his disciple, Antonio Augusto Borges de Medeiros, ran the
southern state of Rio Grande do Sul from 1893 to 1928. They left as their
monument in the state capital, Porto Alegre, a fine collection of public
buildings in the French belle epoque style — a provincial version of the
architectural splendor of Porfirian Mexico City and oligarchical Buenos Aires.
These buildings were doubtless intended persuade the gauchos, as the local
inhabitants call themselves, that they were well on the way to creating a new
Paris in the Pampas. But positivist certainties were to suffer a bruising
encounter with social realities in Brazil.
In 1899, a revolt by
an obscure millenarian preacher, Antonio Conselheiro,
at Canudos, in the parched interior of Bahia state,
mushroomed into a tragic confrontation between modernizing technocracy and the
traditionalism of the neglected poor. Conseiheiro’s
makeshift army of cowherds and peasants defeated three military expeditions,
including a column of a thousand crack federal troops backed by field
artillery. Canudos was finally quelled only after a
four-month siege and weeks of house-to-house fighting involving half the
Brazilian army. This episode left 15,000 dead, including some prisoners
garroted after they had surrendeid.45 From this tragic clash, some members of
Brazil’s political elite drew the conclusion that their country’s common people
were too ‘backward’ to benefit from democracy. But others recognized the need
to spread the benefits of economic growth.
Argentina was less
influenced by positivism. It had embarked on a golden age of economic growth
and civilian rule. In 1862 the country had finally achieved internal unity. It
quickly acquired the rudiments of a nation state: a national legal system, a bureaucracy,
a tax system, a national electoral law, a new national army and two national
newspapers.46 From 1890, Argentina advanced steadily towards democracy: in
1916, Hipólito Yrigoyen, a Radical representing a growing middle class, became
the first president to be elected under universal male suffrage (though the
many foreigners were not allowed to vote). Yet Argentine democracy was being
erected on somewhat shaky foundations. The Pampas, whose development was the
source of the country’s headlong economic growth, had been fully settled by the
First World War. Between them, Buenos Aires and the Pampas accounted for more
than 90 per cent of Argentina’s cars and telephones in the early 192os,
two-fifths of Latin America’s railways, half of the region’s foreign trade and
three-quarters of its educational spending.47 The rest of Argentina’s vast
territory was less prosperous. Liberals from Rivadavia
to Alberdi and Sarmiento had supported American-style homesteading policies,
but had been unable to impose them in the face of oligarchical opposition. The
Pampas had been divided up very unequally: according to the 1914 census, the
largest 584 farms occupied almost a fifth of the total area, and those of over
one thousand hectares (2,470 acres) more than 60 per cent. The mean
average landholding in Argentina was 890 acres, compared with 175 acres in New
South Wales and 130 acres in the United States.48
Across the Rio de la
Plata in Uruguay, the rise of Montevideo as a port serving parts of Argentina
and Brazil similarly spawned a vigorous middle class, reinforced by European
migration. Through the medium of the Colorado party, leaders of this social group
struck a political alliance with the sheep farmers of the interior. Under José Batile y Ordónez (president,
‘903—7 and 1911—15), Uruguay established the foundations of a modern democracy
and one
of the world’s first welfare states. The death penalty was banned and divorce
legalized. Legislation imposed the eight-hour working day, social insurance and
free secondary education. In a foretaste of policies that would be adopted more
widely in the region two decades later, state monopolies were created to run
services from the port to electricity generation and insurance. Thanks to this
social contract forged by Batilismo, as it was
called, Uruguay, the smallest country in South America, has also long been the
most egalitarian. Elsewhere, things were very different.
Land but not Liberty: A Revolution Creates a Corporate State
In September 1910,
delegations from across the world came to Mexico City to celebrate the
centenary of Mexican independence — and a quarter-century of ‘peace, order and
progress’ under Porfirio Diaz. Within months, the appearance of stability was
shattered. After Diaz had claimed to a North American journalist that he would
‘bless’ an opposition, Francisco Madero, the austere scion of a wealthy
northern business family, stood for the presidency against the dictator under
the banner of ‘effective suffrage, no re-election’. After mobilising
support in rallies across the country, he was arrested. Bailed, he escaped to
the United States, and re-entered Mexico in February 1911 at the head of 130
armed men. Other rebels launched local risings, many of them unconnected. By
May, Madero’s troops captured Ciudad Juárez, the most important customs post on
the border with the United States. Faced with a national rebellion that he
could not defeat, Diaz finally resigned.
Madero was a liberal
democrat, an eccentric Spiritist and medium who believed himself chosen to redeem Mexico, and a
man of great personal integrity and decency.49 But he was politically inept. He
disbanded his own troops while allowing supporters of the dictatorship to cling
to positions of power. He failed to reach agreement with Emiliano Zapata, an
Indian peasant leader who had launched his own localized revolution in Morelos,
a small central state whose modernized sugar mills had made voracious encroachmnts on peasant land. In 1913, Madero was
overthrown and murdered in a coup led by Victoriano Huerta, an army commander
backed by the Porfirians and by Henry Lane Wilson,
President William Howard Taft’s meddling ambassador in Mexico City. This coup
served only to intensify discontent. In 1915, Huerta would in turn be defeated
by revolutionary armies sweeping down from the north. They were led by
Francisco Villa, a bandit turned follower of Madero, and Alvaro Obregon, a
farmer from Sonora, an important centre of commercial
agriculture in the north-west, who emerged as the revolution’s most gifted and
ruthless military commander. Venustiano Carranza, another northerner, a
pre-revolutionary state governor but an admirer of Juárez, became president.
The revolution had
long since acquired its own momentum: it had become confused and prolonged
series of local and national struggles over power and land. Zapata had raised
the ancestral Indian demand for land restitution, under the banner (borrowed
via a Mexican anarchist intellectual from Alexander Herzen, a Russian liberal)
of Tierra y Libertad (‘Land and Freedom’). But Zapata lacked interest in
forging national alliances, or in venturing far beyond the villages of Morelos.
He would be betrayed, and shot by federal troops working for Carranza’s
government. In 1916, Carranza convoked a constituent assembly in Querétaro,
north of MexicoCity, to draw up a new constitution.
The resulting document remains in force, though much amended. It was a
compromise between Carranza, a liberal in the nineteenth-century tradition but
an authoritarian one who believed in a strong executive, and radical social
reformers, some of whom had advised Zapata and who had the backing of Obregón.
Notably, the constitution declared both land and the sub-soil to be the
property of the nation — provisions which sounded socialist but were also
throwback to the colonial period when they were vested in the crown.50
It would be another
two decades before local rebellions and violent power struggles among the
commanders of the victorious revolutionary armies died away. What eventually
emerged was a more broadly based nation-state, but one in which power was
ruthlessly centralized — not the liberal democracy which Madero had dreamed.
The post-revolutionary state was largely the creation of three men: two Sonorans, Obregon and Plutarco ElIas
Calles, a conservative former teacher and local police chief; and Lázaro
Cárdenas, the last of the revolutionary generals to become president and a
reformer with socialist leanings. The great achievement of the
post-revolutionary system was bring lasting stability by institutionalizing
political conflict and allowing regular political renewal. Thus, almost
uniquely in Latin America, in Mexico the army was politically neutralized. In
1928, Calles created an official hegemonic political party, known (after 1946)
as the Institutional Revolutionary Party (PRI). The PRI system was a civilian
one. It gave the president the powers of an absolute monarch — but only for six
years. Though was allowed to choose his successor, once out of office the
president was a political nobody. He could not be re-elected. The constitution
was nominally federal. During his presidency (1934—40), Cárdenas suppressed the
remnants the separation of powers: he purged the Congress and the state
governors, and scrapped Carranza’s idea of appointing judges for life. After
Cárdenas, the president had all the levers of power. Congress and governors did
his bidding, but they did form channels through which grievances could be
funneled upwards to the president. All this was carefully legitimated through
elections. The PRI ruled by consent and co-option when possible, and by
electoral fraud and violence only when necessary. The system paid more than
lip-service to the myths of the revolution. Its rule was less elitist than the Porfiriato. Its main characteristics were a corporate
state, social reform and nationalism.
Cárdenas re-organized
the ruling party, as a mass organization on functional lines, with sections for
peasants and workers (and later for middle-class professionals). He put into
practice many of the social aspirations of the radicals in the Querétaro assembly.
He distributed 18.4 million hectares of land among i
million peasants in the form of ejidos, a term which dated from preHispanic communal landholdings. But the land was not
owned directly by the communities and individual farmers, as Zapata had wanted.
Under Cárdenas’s system, while the community enjoyed the use of ejido land, the
state remained its owner. The peasants were tied into the PRI system. They were
demobilized, not empowered. They had won land but not freedom.51 Nor did many
of them escape poverty. Cárdenas also set up a national trade union
confederation. The PRI guaranteed to private industrialists and other
capitalists political stability, subsidised credit
and an expanded and protected domestic market — provided they played the rules
of the political game. The Church, too, was subordinated to the state: the 1916
constitution echoed the fierce anti-clerical laws of Juárez, though these were
applied with decreasing severity after the 1920s.
If the PRI had an
ideology, it was nationalism — the party even adopted the national flag and colours as its own emblems and Mexico came to define itself
in rhetorical opposition to the United States. During the revolution, the
United States twice sent troops to Mexico: in 1914 President Woodrow Wilson
sent marines to Veracruz, to prevent arms from reaching Huerta; when in March
1916 Villa, resentful at American recognition of the Carranza government,
briefly raided the border town of Columbus, New Mexico, Wilson dispatched a
futile ‘punitive expedition’ under General John Pershing (who the following
year commanded a much more significant force in France). Even so, in the view
of Alan Knight, a historian of the revolution, ‘at no point can it be said that
US policy ... was primarily responsible for making or breaking a regime south
of the border. Still less could Standard Oil, or any other corporation, make a
similar claim.’52 But the generous concessions made by the Diaz regime to
foreign capital, especially in mining and oil, angered the revolutionaries.
They argued that the oil companies, both Standard Oil and the British-owned El
Aguila, operated as states within a state, and evaded taxes. In 1938, Cárdenas
acted: the nationalized the oil industry, declaring el
petróleo es nuestro (‘the
oil is ours!’), though he paid compensation. A state company, Petróleos de
Mexico (Pemex), was given a monopoly over the industry. Post-revolutionary
ideology also embraced indigenismo — an intellectual current that called for
the integration of the Indian into the mainstream of society.
At several junctures,
Mexico might have taken the more democratic road espoused by Madero. In the
early 192os, a Liberal Constitutionalist Party pushed for municipal autonomy
and the separation of powers. Such sentiments inspired some of the backers of a
failed rebellion in 1923. In 1929, José Vasconcelos, who as Obregon’s education
minister had been a patron to Diego Rivera and his fellow muralists, stood for
the presidency on a platform of maderista democracy.
But he was defeated by Calles’s machine, which employed the electoral fraud and
strong-arm tactics which would become the PRI system’s less attractive
trademarks.53 In the event, under the PRI Mexico adopted many elements of
corporatism, the ideology championed and discredited by Southern European fascisi in Mussolini’s Italy, Franco’s Spain and Salazar’s
Portugal. But the PRI was not grossly repressive, and it was essentially
pragmatic, not revolutionary. Some of its presidents, like Cárdenas, veered
left. Others were right-wing: Miguel Alemán (1940—6) forged a wartime alliance
with the United States and was friendly to private business. The PRI co-opted
the left — especially writers, artists and academics — but it was also
anti-communist. The PRI’s rule gave Mexico stability, and laid the basis of a
modern nation-state and an industrialized economy. From 1930 until at least
1968 it was highly successful. The economy grew at an annual average rate of 4
per cent from 1929 to 1950, accelerating to 6.4 per cent from 1950 to 198O. On
the whole, there was social peace. The PRI system mimicked the outward forms of
liberal democracy. But in reality it was ‘the perfect dictatorship’, as Vargas
Llosa, the Peruvian novelist, said in 1990. The system had huge defects:
corruption, lack of political and media freedom, massive waste and
inefficiency, all of which became more important as time went by.
The Mexican
revolution and its aftermath had a singular political influence in much of
Spanish-speaking America. Other countries faced the same challenges as Mexico,
of consolidating a modern nation-state, of industrialization, the growth of
cities, the emergence of an organized working class; they, too, saw the rise of
new political currents, such as nationalism, socialism and corporatism. One
early admirer was Victor Raül Haya de la Torre, an exiled Peruvian student
leader. He founded the Alianza Popular Revolucionaria Americana (APRA) as a continental movement
in Mexico City in 1924, and then as a political party in Peru in 1930. APRA’s
founding ‘international maximum programme’ called for
action against Yankee imperialism, the political unity of ‘Indo-America’ (as
Haya called Latin America in deference to its indigenous peoples), the
nationalization of lands and industries, the internationalization of the Panama
Canal, and international solidarity.55 This smacked of radical socialism, but
Haya favored a broad non-communist front, in which the middle class would take
the lead along with workers and indigenous peasants. In his long life — he died
in 1979 while president of a Constituent Assembly preparing the return of
democracy to Peru — his ideas went through various evolutions. ‘Since its
creation, APRA has been a study in contradictions,’ as Julio Cotler, a Peruvian
sociologist, has put it.56 in Peru, APRA would at first flirt with
revolutionary violence, and always retained a conspiratorial flavor. But Haya’s
preference, if allowed, was to compete for power through elections. He said
that APRA would respect democratic liberties. Haya became increasingly
conservative, but many in his party yearned for a Mexican-style corporate state
and nationalization of American mining companies in Peru.57 The army repeatedly
intervened to prevent APRA winning power; it would take office only in 1985,
under the inept leadership of Alan Garcia. Even so, Haya was a hugely
influential figure in his country’s politics and beyond. He supported the
campaign in Nicaragua of Augusto Sandino, a dissident liberal general, against
a government backed by American marines.58 APRA became the transmission belt
for the ideas of the Mexican revolution to South America.
The Liberal order had
lasted for two decades longer in South America than in Mexico. Its death knell
was sounded by the Wall Street crash of October 1929 — as it was in Europe. If
the Great Depression did not amount to a decisive turning point in Latin America’s
economic history, it certainly marked a sharp political rupture. The impact of
the depression on employment and living standards was severe. Ten countries in
the region saw the value of their exports fall by more than half between 1928
and 1932. No other country in the Western world was as badly affected by the
crash as Chile, whose trade fell by 83 per cent between 1929 and 1932. In Chile
and Cuba income per head fell by a third.59 Many governments defaulted on their
foreign debts for the first time since the mid-nineteenth century. Across the
region, the depression prompted discontent and agitation by fledgling labor
unions, many of anarcho-syndicalist persuasion, and small left-wing political
parties. In El Salvador, an attempt at an insurrection by the small Communist
Party was crushed in a bloodbath. In Peru, risings by APRA and the Communists
were repressed. In Chile, a brief socialist republic was declared by Marmaduque Grove, an air-force officer and uncle of
Salvador Allende. Cuba saw a short- lived revolution by radical students and
army sergeants.
Conservatives felt
threatened by mass demonstrations and the new leftwing parties. Some looked to
military rule to save them from the masses. Some were attracted by fascism,
especially in its Mediterranean form of corporatism. Many on the left, too,
would be attracted by corporatism. In Latin America, Mussolini and Franco were
more influential than Marx and Lenin. Within two years of the Wall Street
crash, army officers had sought or taken power in Argentina, Brazil, Chile,
Peru and three Central American countries (Guatemala, El Salvador and
Honduras).60 In 1933, the army took power in Cuba. In Argentina, the crash
ended fifty years of broadly stable civilian rule. It found the second
administration of Hipólito Yrigoyen, the elderly leader of the Radical Party,
fiscally exposed: his efforts to cut a vast budget deficit undermined his
political support. In September 1930, a military junta took power. It was not
particularly repressive, and it presaged a decade of civilian- military rule.
But in deciding that it would accept as legal the junta’s edict, the Supreme
Court elaborated a dangerous doctrine of revolución triunfante — or might is right.61 For half a century after
i3o, that doctrine brought Argentina instability and the subordination of
civilian politics to the armed forces. In Chile, the lasting impact was in
reverse: a wave of protest and anti-militarism swept away Carlos Ibañez, a
moderate conservative military dictator. Two brief military interventions
followed. But exceptionally, democratic and constitutional rule was
strengthened, lasting until the overthrow of Salvador Allende in 1973.
Exceptional, too, was Colombia: in an election in 1930, the Liberals ended
fifty years of Conservative rule, helped by the impact of the crash and their
opponents’ divisions. A period of vigorous social reform followed. Many of the
Latin American economies recovered fairly swiftly from the depression, thanks
both to renewed export growth and Keynesian measures of state intervention and
import-substitution industrialisation. But politics
had changed for ever. Only in a few smaller countries
did ‘oligarchical’ liberalism survive the crash.
Mexico was unique in
institutionalizing corporatist nationalism. But its revolution was strongly
echoed four decades later in Bolivia. In 1951, the National Revolutionary
Movement (MNR), a mainly middle-class party but with support among miners,
workers and peasant farmers, won an election. Robbed of power by a military
coup, in 1952 it staged a popular rising. For three days, the MNR’s urban
militias fought army conscripts in La Paz. The battle was turned in the MNR’s
favor by the arrival of a contingent of armed miners, and by splits in the
security forces. Some 500 people died, but the old order had been toppled.62
The MNR’s leader, Victor Paz Estenssoro, a university teacher of economics, was
installed as president. His government enacted universal suffrage, nationalized
the tin mines which provided the main export, and broke up most of the
haciendas on the Altiplano, handing over the land as family plots to the Indian
resident serfs. A serious effort was made to provide universal education, at
least at primary level. And for the first time Indians were allowed to enter
the Plaza Murillo, La Paz’s main square and the site of the cathedral, the
presidential palace and the Congress. The MNR would be the dominant political
force in Bolivia for the next half- century, but it neither achieved the
supremacy of the PRI nor tamed the armed forces.
Elsewhere,
corporatism tended to be articulated by charismatic nation- builders —
old—fashioned caudillos in a new, more powerful incarnation. In this form,
political scientists have often preferred to label corporatism as populism. The
most prominent populists included Brazil’s Getulhio
Vargas, who as governor of Rio Grande do Sul was heir to that state’s
positivist tradition, and who became president through a civilian-military coup
in 1930. Vargas ruled as a dictator from 1937 to r945, and then was elected
president again in 1950. In Argentina, Juan Perón, an army colonel, ruled from
1945 to 1955; the movement he founded has remained the dominant political force
in Argentina to this day. But Perón did not hold a monopoly on Argentine
populism: Yrigoyen’s Radicals also had strong populist streaks. In Venezuela, Acción Democratica (AD), with
which Peru’s APRA had especially close links, evolved from populism to social
democracy. AD dominated Venezuelan politics for much of the period between the
1940S until the rise of Hugo Chavez. There were some differences between these
movements. For example, Perón’s government of 1945—55 was the closest Latin
America came to a fascist regime. It gave refuge to at least i8o Nazis and
their collaborators, including such notorious figures as Adolf Eichmann, Eduard
Roschmann, Joseph Mengele (who was later in Brazil) and Klaus Barbie (who moved
on to Bolivia).63 During the dictatorship of the Estado Novo (‘New State’),
Vargas also flirted with fascism. Haya de la Torre was, at least for parts of
his career, closer to democratic socialism though APRA was organised
on corporatist lines. Of the larger countries, only Colombia and Chile remained
relatively aloof from populism.
In Latin America,
unlike in Russia and the United States, populism was an overwhelmingly urban
movement and ideology.64 It was above all a political response to urbanization,
and to what was seen as the elitist and exclusionary politics of the pre-193o ‘oligarchical’
republics. It reflected what Jorge Castafleda, a
Mexican writer and politician, has called the ‘unfulfilled Latin American dream
of painless modernity’.65 The original populist movements flourished from the
mid-192os to the mid-196os — though populism has enjoyed an unanticipated
recent revival in the region. They promoted industrialisation,
a policy on which local industrialists, the middle class and organized labor
could all agree. Populist movements were multi-class electoral coalitions.
Their leaders deliberately talked of el pueblo (the
people) rather than, say, la clase obrera (the working class). As well as nationalism, they
injected the concept of lo popular into Latin American political vocabulary
(meaning for and by the people), as in their claim to lead ‘popular’
governments. Their programme involved protection and
subsidies for local industry, and political representation and welfare
provision for the urban masses. This in turn involved an expansion of the role
of the state in the economy and society, which generated new jobs for the middle
classes. Populist movements opposed foreign domination and the power of what
they called the agro-export ‘oligarchy’. Although
they often proclaimed themselves to be ‘revolutionary’, these movements were
reformist — unlike parties of the Marxist left, they aimed to mitigate class
conflict rather than stimulate it. Even so, populist movements were often seen
as a threat by conservative agro-exporting interests
(and by the United States). In a way they were: they - sought to redistribute
resources from farming to the cities. The result was that populists were often
the target of repression. Another distinguishing characteristic of populist movements
was their reliance on charismatic leadership. The populist leaders were often
great orators or, if you prefer, demagogues. Ecuador’s most emblematic populist
leader, José Maria Velasco, famously said: ‘Give me a balcony and I will become
president.’ This was no idle boast: his campaigning skills saw him elected
president five times— though his lack of governing skills, and the fierce
opposition he generated among conservatives, saw him ousted four times by the
army. Such leadership exalted an almost mystical bond between leader and
masses. This sometimes involved the use of religious imagery or techniques, as
with Haya de la Torre.
For better or for worse, populism was the political vehicle through which many
Latin American countries entered the modern era of mass politics and bigger
government. Its achievements included a boost to industrialization, and an
improvement in social conditions for favored sectors of the urban workforce.
Workers received tangible benefits, such as paid holidays, pensions and health
provision. Those benefits were sufficient to encourage remarkably durable
loyalty among the beneficiaries, as the longevity of the PRI and Peronism in
particular illustrate. Perón’s social reforms deprived Argentina’s small
Socialist and Communist parties of working-class support; they were never to
regain it. Whereas liberals and positivists had often looked abroad for
inspiration, populists promoted a ‘national culture’, rescuing indigenous
people and their cultural artifacts from official neglect.
In these respects,
populism played an analogous role to social democracy in Europe. But there were
important differences. Overall, populism had a negative impact on Latin
American democracy and development. Four defects stand out. First, although it
employed electoral means, populism was in many ways less than democratic. As
Paul Drake puts it, populist leaders ‘were devoted to expanding popular
participation but not necessarily through formal, Western democratic
mechanisms’.66 Perón, Vargas, and Haya ‘repeatedly exhibited dictatorial
propensities toward their followers and opponents. They apparently favored
controlled, paternalistic mobilization of the masses more than uninhibited,
pluralistic, democratic competition.’67 In fairness, their conservative opponents,
too, were often less than democratic. In Argentina, even a liberal such as
Jorge Luis Borges, the writer, came to believe that Peronism showed that his
country was not ‘ready’ for democracy.
He argued at one
point that military dictatorship was a necessary evil to prevent Peronism from
remaining in power. A second, linked failing was the reliance on charismatic
leadership. Max Weber, the German sociologist, defined charismatic authority as
being exercised by an individual who is ‘set apart from ordinary men and
treated as endowed with supernatural, superhuman, or at least specifically
exceptional qualities’.68 Weber contrasted it with two other forms of
authority, traditional and rational-legal. As Weber’s definition makes clear,
charismatic leadership is inimical to the rule of law
— or indeed the separation hf powers and the construction of democratic
institutions. Populist leaders relied on a direct bond between themselves and
the masses: not for nothing did they emerge simultaneously with the radio and
the cinema. Eva Perón had worked as an actress in radio soaps; like FDR, Getülio Vargas made regular radio broadcasts to Brazilians.
They established political clienteles, rather than creating citizenship.
Benefits came from loyalty, not as a matter of right. The reliance on charisma
was one reason why populism was inherently unstable.
Third, perhaps the
most disappointing feature of populism was its failure to make a serious attack
on inequality. In contrast to Mexico and Bolivia, where revolutions broke the
political power of the traditional hacendados, other
populist leaders usually excluded the poorest sections of the masses
— the peasantry — from their coalitions. Populist governments made no attempt
to extend the franchise to illiterates, nor to implement land reform. And in
attempting to transfer resources from agriculture to industry, such as by
controlling food prices, they were impoverishing peasant as well as landlord.
Their reliance on inflation, rather than thoroughgoing tax reforms, to finance
government hurt the poor disproportionately too. This was but one aspect of a
fourth defect of populism: its economic policy. Populist governments were not
alone in pursuing statist protectionism: by the 196os many military
dictatorships did too. But the constant tension in populist governments between
industrialization and welfarism (as Drake puts it) led them to rely on
over-expansionary macroeconomic policies and made them prey to extreme economic
volatility. While claiming to champion the creation of a modern state, the
clientelist approach to politics adopted by many populist leaders led them to
create inefficient public bureaucracies stuffed with their supporters.
Some of these
weaknesses, combined with the opposition that populists aroused among some
powerful conservative groups, meant that from the 19308 on, Latin America’s
incipient democracies were subject to chronic instability, and to what came to
be known as the pendulum effect, as civilian governments alternated with
dictatorships. In the aftermath of the Second World War, an external conflict
would intensify these political battles in Latin America, to tragic effect.
1. Many believe that
the army overreacted. Debate still rages as to whether the M19 was acting at
the behest of drug traffickers. The files of many drug cases were among those
consumed by fire during the assault.
2. Krauze, Mexico:
Biography of Power, p. xlii.
3. These estimates
are from Alexander Von Humboldt, the great German scientist- explorer who
travelled widely in Spanish America in 1799—1804. They are quoted in Lynch,
John (1986), The Spanish American Revolutions 1808—182 6, 2nd edition, WW
Norton & Company, New York, p. 19.
4. Ibid., p. 2.
5. Ibid., p. i8.
6. Carr, Raymond
(ed.) (2000), Spain: A History, Oxford, p. 198.
7. Parry, J H,
Sherlock, Philip and Maingot, Anthony (1987), A Short History of the West
Indies, 4th edition, Macmillan, p. 140.
8. France did not recognise Haiti’s independence until 1825, and then only
after the new state agreed to pay reparations of 150 million francs (later
reduced to 6o million); Haiti did not repay the resulting debt until 1922. In
January 2004, Haiti’s government commemorated the bi-centenary of independence.
Jean-Bertrand Aristide, who was to be overthrown shortly afterwards, used the
occasion to demand that France repay the reparations which, with interest, he
said, amounted to $21.7 billion.
9. Walker, Charles F
(1999), Smoldering Ashes: Cuzco and the Creation of Republican Peru, 1780—1840,
Duke-University Press, p. 13.
10. Lynch, The
Spanish American Revolutions, p. 24.
11. Maxwell, Kenneth
(2003), ‘Why Was Brazil Different?’, in Naked Tropics: Essays on Empire and
Other Rogues, Routledge, p. 156. See also Wilcken, Patrick (2004), Empire
Adrift, Bloomsbury.
12. Harvey, Robert
(2000), Liberators: Latin America’s Struggle for Independence 1810—1930, John
Murray, Part 4.
13.
Bushnell/Macaulay, The Emergence of Latin America, p.59.
14.
Fernández-Armesto, The Americas: A Hemispheric History, pp. 126—7.
15. Thomas, Hugh (iz), Cuba or The Pursuit of Freedom, Eyre & Spotiswoode, pp. 45—56.
16. Ibid., p. 46.
17. See Vargas Llosa,
Liberty for Latin America, pp. 28—9.
18. Quoted in
Galeano, Open Veins of Latin America, p.37.
19. Basadre, Jorge (1987), Peru: Problema
y Posibilidad, 5th edition, Libreria
Studium, Lima, p. 281.
20. Panama was a
province of Colombia until 1903, when it declared independence in a rebellion
inspired by the United States.
21. The author of the
phrase was John L O’Sullivan, the young editor of the New York Morning News. In
1845 he wrote that the US claim to the Oregon Territory was justified ‘by the
right of our manifest destiny to overspread and to possess the whole of the
continent which Providence has given us for the development of the great
experiment of liberty and federated self-government entrusted to us.’
22. Some Latin
Americans had long seen the potential for river transport. ‘The Mississippi is
not more available for commerce than the Paraná; nor do the Ohio, Illinois or
Arkansas water a larger or richer territory than the Pilcomayo, Bermejo,
Paraguay and so many other great rivers,’ noted Domingo Faustino Sarmiento, an
Argentine writer and later president, in 1845.
23. ‘In the Central
Andes, the majority of people traditionally resided above 2,500 metres, where adverse corollaries of altitude include
rugged terrain, fragile topography, steep slopes, poor soils, limited farmland,
short growing seasons, high winds, aridity, elevated solar radiation, erratic
rainfall, precarious nutrition, cold and hypoxia. Hypoxia is the technical term
for low oxygen tension due to elevational decrease in barometric pressure. It
is a pervasive source of chronic stress on all life ... cold and anoxia oblige
people to eat more ... Consequently, it costs measurably more to support life
and civilisation in mountains than in lowlands.’
Moseley, Michael E (2001), The Incas and Their Ancestors, Thames and Hudson,
London, p. 27. The author is referring to pre-conquest life, but many of these
factors apply today. Tourists to Cusco or to Lake Titicaca get a brief taste of
some of these deprivations.
24. Lewis, Cohn M,
‘Public Policy and Private Initative: Railway
Building in São Paulo 1860—89’, University of London, Institute of Latin
American Studies Research Papers No. 26, 1991.
25. Sarmiento,
Domingo F (1998), Facundo: or, Civilization and Barbarism, Penguin Classics,
London, p..
26.
Bushnell/Macaulay, The Emergence of Latin America, p. 53.
27. Lamounier, BolIvar
(2oo5) Da Independência a Lula: dois séculos de polItica brasileira, Augurium
Editora, São Paulo, p. 80.
28. Ibid., pp. 43—68.
29. Skidmore, Thomas
E (1999), Brazil: Five Centuries of Change, Oxford University Press, p. 48.
30. Lynch, John
(2006), Simon BolIvar: A Life, Yale University Press,
p. xi.
31. Bolivar, Simon,
El Libertador, p. xxx.
32. Bolivar, SimOn, ‘The Jamaica Letter’, in El Libertador, p. 23.
33. Lynch, Simon BolIvar, p.77.
34. Colombia’s FARC
guerrillas and Cuba’s communist regime also pay rhetorical obeisance to Boilvar.
35. Lynch, SimOn BolIvar, p.304.
36. Lynch, John
(2001), Argentine Caudillo: Juan Manuel de Rosas, Scholarly Resources,
Wilmington, Delaware, p.72.
37. There were
occasional exceptions. In Colombia, a Liberal constitution in 1853 included
universal male suffrage and popular election of the Supreme Court. In one
province, the Liberals enacted female suffrage, but this was struck down by the
Court before it could be implemented. Bushnell/Macaulay, The Emergence of Latin
America, p. 212. Chile abolished the property qualification (though not the
literacy requirement) for voting in 1874 (ibid., p. 237).
38. Shumway, Nicolas
The Invention of Argentina, University of California Press, p. 183.
39. Thorp, Progress,
Poverty and Exclusion, pp. 1—2.
40. See Wiarda, The
Soul of Latin America, Chapter 6.
41. Klein, Herbert S,
‘Migracao Internacional na
Historia das Americas’, in Fausto, Boris (ed.) (1999), Fazer a America: A Imigracao em Massa para a America
Latina, Editora da Universidade
de São Paulo, pp. 13—31.
42. Quoted in Krauze,
Mexico: Biography of Power, pp. 217 and 231.
43. Ibid., p. 219.
44. Not to be
confused with Benjamin Constant, a liberal politician of the French revolution
after whom the Brazilian was named.
45. For an extraordinary
account by an observer of this campaign, see da Cunha, Euclides, Os Sert0es, translated as Rebellion in the Backlands,
Picador, 1995. Mario Vargas Llosa drew heavily on da Cunha’s book in his novel
War of the End of the World. During the Canudos
campaign, the army set up a camp on Monte Favela, a bill overlooking the
settlement. As a result, the word favela entered the Portuguese language to
describe a shantytown.
For updates click
homepage here