Plots go far to
explain how past glories degenerated into today's tribulations. Thus when in 1913
The Young Turks (or, more formally, the Committee of Union and Progress, CUP),
deposed, the Ottoman sultan, Abdulhamit II this was
explained as a Jewish Conspiracy which would have next inspire the Armenian Holocoast. While all evidence points to the Young Turks
being primarily made up of Turkish-speaking, Muslims, even the British
ambassador in Istanbul, Gerard Lowther, insisted that the movement was inspired
and led by Jews and Freemasons. Middle Eastern Christians first picked up these
European notions, then passed them along to Muslims. Already in May 1909, the
Syrian Central Committee, a Paris-based Christian group favoring French rule in
the Levant, wrote about Jewish and Masonic leadership of the Young Turks; the
committee postulated Zionist efforts to destroy the Ottoman Empire in pursuit
of a Jewish state in Palestine. Even today, fundamentalists hark back to the
Jewish overthrow of Sultan Abdulhamit II as one of
the key events in the decline of Islam in modern times and frequently cite it
as a leading act of Jewish perfidy. They portray the Ottoman king as a staunch
Muslim whom the Jews had to sideline if they were to take over in Palestine.
Yet similar is also
claimed otherwise, Bulent Ecevit, the leftist Turkish leader, accused
Washington of encouraging Armenians to make territorial demands on both
Azerbaijan and Turkey. Why? Because "the United States is planning to give
Armenia a role in the Caucasus similar to that played by Israel in the Middle
East." (Paraphrased in Mohamed Heikal, The Sphinx and the Commudar: The Rise and Fall of Soviet Influence in the
Middle East, New York, 1978, p. 186.) Nakhichevan's President Haydar
Aliyev, seeing Armenia as the U.S. base in the Caucasus, also drew the analogy
to Israel. This embryonic parallel to the U.S.-Israel nexus suggests that
Israel need not be unique in the Middle Eastern imagination; any non-Muslim can
enter the same twilight of puppet and puppeteer. Some Young Turk thinkers had
re-labeled Buddhism as proto-Islam in appreciation of the Japanese military
success against Russia in 1905.
And another powerful
example of appropriation was the Indian Muslim reaction to the death of Mustafa
Kemal Ataturk. The event created immense excitement. Prayer meetings were held
in all major mosques of the subcontinent, in some cases involving several hundreds
of thousands of Muslims. But the Ataturk that Indians mourned and the Atatiirk who had emerged during the founding years of the
Turkish republic had preciously little in common. The front page of Inqilab, a
respectable, even high-brow paper, reported the following on 10 November 1938:
shortly before his death Atatiirk briefly awoke from
a coma and conveyed a message to his servant, which the latter was told to pass
on to the 'Islamic Nation' (millat Islamiyya). Atatiirk is reported
to have sighed 'Allah' and then passed out of consciousness.
This is hardly
credible for a leader who died of the effects of life-long alcoholism, and
endeavored to break the link between Turkish Islam and the world Muslim
community. Thus it is remarkable how the Indo-Muslim account literally and
shamelessly colonizes the Turkish historical experience for its own purpose. To
make the case more clear, Sir Sikandar Hayat Khan, the Unionist Premier of the
Punjab, declared in a public speech, that the Muslim Ataturk had been more
successful in overcoming the world than Hitler and Mussolini (the most
cherished non-Muslim Fascist icons), and that the Muslims of Lahore should not
believe what the non-Muslim English language papers had to say about their
hero's hostility towards religion. (Letter Diwan Chaman Lal to Acharya Ram 11
November 1938, quoted in NAI: File-Home Political- 28/18/38, Passport Dewan
Chaman Lal. Activities of Chaman Lal, author of the prohibited book “The
Vanishing Empire”.)
Other speakers and
newspaper commentators noted maliciously that Hindu shops and offices had not
responded to the general hartal, which the Muslims of Lahore had called to
commemorate their Leader's death, adding to the general feeling that Ataturk
belonged to the Muslim community, and to nobody else. There was, of course,
again an element of symbolic transfer of power involved: both the enforcement
and the defiance of the call for a close-down could produce states of
empowerment that were in a way directly linked to the perceived power of their
symbolic cause, Ataturk.
The Economy of Transnational Liberalism
In Turkey during the
early 1960’s then, the erosion of social welfare projects and the rise of
money-capital’s power, as opposed to industrial-capital, coincided with the petro-dollar boom in the Middle East, especially in Saudi
Arabia. Within that nexus, the class and ideological interests of the Saudi
elite and that of the transnational liberalism mentioned in the previous
chapter corresponded.
As explained however,
it is important that we first present what could be said to be a postscript to
our earlier part 1, and 2 excursion into Globalization, this time pointing to
the development of modern economics as it also became to be of influence in
Turkey.
For this we need to
understand that the international political economy (IPE) literature generally
identifies three successive international regimes that affected the economic
and political relationships among nations before contemporary neo-liberalism’s
free floating exchange rate system. The first regime is the international gold
standard, which was a fixed exchange rate regime that pegged each national
currency to a fixed gold value. This in turn determined the exchange rates of
different national currencies in relation to each other. By fixing the values
of currencies to a stable index, the British tried to facilitate the
international flow of commodities. Britain assumed leadership because of its
position in the world economy. It was the most industrialized country, driven
by a rapid accumulation of wealth and governmental policies such as the repeal
of Corn Laws in 1846, which restricted agricultural imports. By cutting the
power of the agricultural elite, industrial capitalists in Britain not only altered
the domestic balance of power in their favor but also opened up the British
economy to foreign imports. While that provided a common good to other
countries (France, Germany, the United States) in terms of rising exports in
the international system, these countries consented to lower their tariff
barriers against British goods too. Starting with the 1860 Cobden-Chevalier
treaty between Britain and France, numerous arrangements emerged to lower trade
restrictions around Europe (O’Brien, 2002).
While the industrial
revolution and naval power underpinned British power, other emerging industrial
countries grew steadily under the protection of British imperial liberalism.
After the 1870s, with the first depression of capitalist economies worldwide,
these fledging economies and their political elites increasingly competed with
Britain (Arrighi, 2003). According to Wallerstein, mercantilism and the
protection of domestic trade from outside competition became the favored
approach, as the continental powers sought to resolve the domestic and external
problems caused by the Franco-Prussian War.
The technological
investments by these competing powers surpassed that of British liberal economy
and erased most of the competitive power overseas of the country’s cheap
manufactured products. This further aggravated nationalistic fervor among these
new industrial economies to secure overseas colonies for raw materials and
markets. Increasingly Germans, Americans, and the Japanese tried to develop
superior navies and acquire territorial space, seeking to colonize the rest of
the world (Wallerstein, 1999). In reality the international gold standard and
laissez faire capitalism did not survive because an invisible hand could not
regulate commodity flows and capital stocks. Rather, international investors
and traders believed that the Bank of England could compensate any demand for
gold in exchange of pounds, thus sustaining the system if there was any
disequilibrium in demand and supply. Also as Barry Eichengreen
argued, the pre World war- I political environment
within the core countries of the system largely isolated central banks and
monetary decision-makers from political pressures or associated democratic
accountability. The working class and labor organizations were not mature
enough to counter the outlook of free market capitalists. The unemployment problem
during the years of financial and economic crisis was perceived as independent
from monetary policy decisions of central banks. Nearly everyone within the
gold standard system had accepted the hegemony of liberal ideas, the
preeminence of which corresponded to an era in which finance capital was the
dominant faction of capitalist class (Eichengreen,
1996), (Pijl, 1984). This rise of financial capital
mainly stemmed from an increasing concentration of wealth in fewer hands
through uneven but rapid capital accumulation in a free market environment. The
industrial capital was largely absorbed by banks and financial companies as the
domestic rate of profits from industrial production began to fall, a
development which pressured capitalists to look for overseas markets since the
return of capital/input ratio in advanced economies was decreasing due to
exhaustion of profitable markets (Brewer, 1980).
In the 1890s new
advocacy groups emerged in the Mid-Western United States and Britain whose
demands included domestic subsidies for agriculture and anti-monopoly laws
against the ferocious encroachments of finance capital and monopolies into the
lives of ordinary farmers. In the context of rising unemployment and poverty,
the working class began to organize in inner cities, as the adverse effects of
the 1873 and 1896 business cycles were deeply felt. Meanwhile, the anti-money
capital discourse of small business found new allies among the ranks of
nationalist industrial capital. The rhetoric of anti-Semitism and Anglo-Saxon
supremacy coupled with the reification of “productive” capital against
money-capital and of the inherent industriousness of Protestants all hinted at
the coming era of colonization. These ideas resonated with a broader public, at
the same time elites in the newly industrialized powers saw that in order to
compete with overseas rivals they needed to directly control markets and
shipping routes. This would be more profitable than just competing in capital
exports (Pijl, 1984) According to Kees Van Der Pijl, the fruition of these imperialist plans evolved
differently in the Anglo-Saxon world than in other countries such as Germany
and Italy that industrialized late. In these countries, the bourgeoisie was
weak and dependent upon the feudal aristocracy of the old regime. State
monopolies and ultra nationalistic tendencies were the results of this class
balance of power. In the meantime in the Anglo-Saxon world, former leader
Britain and the American elite preferred to subscribe to the idea of universal
good, which is still espoused today in the ideology of the white man’s
burden—that is the obligation to civilize “savage” peoples for their own good.
The social struggles
that ensued after the turn of twentieth century were largely between industrial
capital and money capital within core countries. However, the growing
assertiveness of the working class and its popular pressure over economic and
political decisions aggravated the systemic crisis that indirectly strengthened
the statemonopoly current of industrial capital.
Beginning in the 1890s, the United States, France, and Germany increased their
defense budgets, specially their naval expenses (Pijl,
1984). These popular pressures and assertive nationalist agendas pushed the
ailing British Empire closer to the United States, while Britain had profound
disagreements with the French and Germans over the colonization of Africa. With
this development the main psychological effect that kept the gold standard
system and laissez faire capitalism intact, the international solidarity that
supported other central banks or governments decisions on exchange rates and
convertibility was wounded. Increasingly international investors tested the
ability of the Bank of England to satisfy the gold reserve requirements of the
international monetary system. Unlike what economists thought, uncontrolled
financial flows and currency trading did not always spur growth or create
employment. Sensing the weaknesses of governments, investors often initiated
speculative attacks on currencies. They demanded more and more gold from
governments, who tried to balance exchange rates through selling gold from
reserves, which in turn depreciated the reserves and made them more vulnerable.
In an earlier era, these governments relied on others’ gold transfers to the
problem country due to the aforementioned international solidarity. Perhaps in
the early nineteenth century, when central banks were insulated from domestic
popular pressure demanding they tackle unemployment or spur domestic
consumption levels, governments could allocate much more resources to protect
their exchange rate parities. However, during the 1910s, with capitalist rivalry
abroad and domestic working class demands, economic decisions had to follow
politics (Eichengreen, 1996) (Madison, 1997).
With the end of the
World War I, which epitomized the climax of capitalist rivalry among Western
powers, the worldwide balance of power was reconfigured. With the destruction
of the war upon its economy and overseas markets, the British Empire became a shadow
of its former self. France, Germany, and Italy all lined up behind the United
States, since the world’s largest debtor became the biggest creditor after the
four years of increased domestic demand and growth. New York City and Wall
Street gradually took over financial leadership from London.
On the Eastern front,
with the Russian government overthrown and the successful conclusion of
Bolshevik revolution, tensions sharpened between the capitalist class and the
industrial working class. In order to prevent more radical turbulence from
decolonized nations or the international proletariat, U.S. president Wilson
launched his liberal offensive in his Fourteen Points, which emphasized the
self-determination of newly decolonized nations. His main aim was to pacify
radical tendencies through supporting nationalist but “liberal” minded (i.e.,
capitalist friendly) elites within the Third World. However, in the tumultuous
years of the interwar period, the American liberal offensive, or the
state-monopolist project of corporate liberalism, could not be successful.
First internal alliances within American ruling class were still favoring more
or less finance capitals’ conception of free market capitalism. Second, in
Europe and in the United States, there were groups whose anti-Semitism and
reactionary nationalistic outlook, whose predatory aims began the war,
prevented any international reconciliation over monetary policy or strategy.
In the environment of
the late 1920s declining gold reserves in war-torn countries, which had
problems with inflation and unbacked paper currency usage, forced governments
to accept free floating exchange rates due to impossibility of defending pegged
currencies. After 1925 European countries somewhat stabilized their economies
and exchange rates by resorting to different variations. Most countries started
to accumulate foreign currencies like the U.S. dollar in their reserves, as the
situation after the war made it almost impossible for individual countries to
obtain large amounts of gold. Those uncertainties increased the anarchic price
determining tendencies of the free market, which were instrumental in
generating the 1929 market crash and ensuing Great Depression. First of all,
vulnerable financial conditions were incentives for financial speculators to
make quick money from currency speculation or attacks on pegs that countries
tried to protect (Eichengreen, 1996) (Pijl, 1984). These capital movements were mostly driven by
short-term profiteering, which fostered non-productive or reckless investments
in world economy. They also disillusioned capitalists since, in the post-1917
anti-union era of the red scare, the discrepancy between rising profits and real
wages created a demand side problem. However, luxurious consumption and
financial speculation provided some breathing space for free markets, creating
a sense that there would be no downturn in the economy. In 1929, starting with
commodity prices and corporate profits, world capitalism saw a general decline
in profits and production. Up to that time, the free reign of corporations over
other social forces, especially in the United States, gave a false sense of
confidence to capitalists, as their share of wealth or surplus value increased
proportionately to their increasing strength vis-à-vis other classes.
In the sphere of
agriculture, the glut of goods pushed prices down, which directed farmers
“rationally” to produce more in order to make more profits with cheaper
agricultural commodities. However, that individual decision further depressed
prices due to lack of effective demand. In the industrial sector, with its
ferocious anti-unionism, capitalists had already comfortably pruned all the
gains of the working class, which in turn created an enormously unequal
distribution of income. Conspicuous consumption of the rich and the increasing
production of monopolies to increase their stock prices generated the
impression that the United States was on the brink of an unprecedented growth
cycle. The false illusions were dashed when the U.S stock market collapsed on
October 29, 1929.
Although the major
signs of depression were apparent, conservative laissez faire economists could
not ameliorate the malaise and prevent the ultimate collapse. As factories were
closing and firing their employees, the central banks were helpless in the framework
of liberal economics. The situation was aggravated by the erection of tariff
barriers in major capitalist countries, which further depreciated the volume of
world trade. Classical economists even thought that the problem would be solved
by depreciating wages, as high wages caused decreased profits. If no one
intervenes, or even if the money supply is constrained to reduce overproduction
or to prevent inflation, the markets would automatically correct themselves
naturally.
The Hoover
administration’s series of policies proved disastrous to the American economy.
In a chain reaction, Western European economies went into recession, as most of
them were financially tied to the American banking system and industrial sector
in the aftermath of the First World War. The most severe results were seen in
Germany, which defaulted on its war reparations. The crisis created the
plausible terrain for the ascendance of socially-minded corporate liberalism in
Western capitalist countries. Laissez faire economics and its staunchest
supporter, money capital, virtually receded from the forefront of politics
during the turbulence of Great Depression (Brewer, 1980) (Temin, 1989)
(Eichengreen,1996).
British political
economist John Maynard Keynes found a very simple cure to the Depression.
According to his theory, most of the poor save money in difficult times,
resulting in the hoarding of too much money and the dwindling of demand. To
reinvigorate demand, governments should enlarge the money supply, or in extreme
conditions like the Great Depression, they should spend money, which in turn
encourages others to spend. By providing money to consumers, confidence levels
would increase and have a wealth effect that boosts employment (Keynes, 1936).
Keynesian ideas were put into effect after 1933 and gained full recognition
after 1938. The appeal of Keynes’s policy prescriptions was bolstered during
Second World War, as the Roosevelt administration generated a large economic
boom with the help of war expenditures and decisions that enhanced public
spending and employment.
Throughout the war
years, world governments and dominant classes learned that they could control
inflation, unemployment, and business cycles through Keynesian fiscal and
monetary policies. Before exploring the postwar period, it is necessary to
understand the underlying production relations and ideological struggles of the
Keynesian era.
The Fordist mode of
accumulation was first initiated by American industrialist Henry Ford at his
auto factory in Dearborn, Michigan. As we saw above during the Depression years
and in the aftermath of the World War, most of capital investments suffered from
a fall in the rate of profit, which created unemployment and production cuts.
In that context firms that innovated new technology achieved increased
productivity and were more competitive than their rivals who remained committed
to old forms of craft production techniques. Old craft production techniques
provided too much freedom to skilled workers in terms of organizing the pace
and form of their work. That system depended on a piece by piece wage payment
system that not only encouraged the aforementioned tendencies, but also, by
increasing the leverage of the worker over the conditions of his/her
employment, created problems for capitalists in subjugating the workforce to
factory discipline. Since the control of the labor process was an essential component
of extracting surplus value in the tumultuous years of 1920s, these weaknesses
on the part of capital occasionally spurred industrial crises. Craft production
usually aimed to maximize absolute surplus value, which was crippled by the
actions of industrial workers and could not compete with the new Fordist
emphasis on the extraction of relative surplus value (Rupert, 2000).
The Fordist
accumulation model itself did not achieve complete dominance without class
struggle. Struggles between the Congress of Industrial Organizations (CIO) and
industrial giants rendered it difficult for capital to impose this system of
accumulation onto the body of industrial relations in the United States. These
struggles led to a different system of industrial relations than Western
Europe. This new model, using Taylor’s production techniques, especially the
assembly line, increased the pace of work through the complete mechanization
and automation of the work. This minimized the worker’s discretionary power
over his or her work as the new discipline of assembly line tied individual
worker to the whole body of the workforce, thereby emphasizing not the quality
of the individual piece but the whole collective effort. This created a rift
between skilled and unskilled workers due to the fact that mechanized
production demanded little creativity from the worker; indeed, it reduced their
creativity by exposing them to excruciatingly boring repetitions. Also, by
incorporating science and technological progress into the production process,
Fordism increased productivity to unthinkable levels compared to old forms of
craft production. In turn, mechanization allowed Ford to reduce prices and
marginalize competitors in the market. Ford also encountered massive resistance
to his schemes, as turnover rates, sicknesses, and absences convoluted his
profit raising plans. These forms of worker resistance, coupled with the CIO’s
victories against anti-unionist Ford in 1937, turned the attention of the
capitalist strata to the social and ideological aspects of the class struggle.
Though Ford’s
sociology department with its Protestant work ethic guidelines was not
successful, Ford Foundation grants and Ford’s reconciliation with labor on
cutting work time and raising real wages were. The aftermath of the 1937 Second
New Deal offered fertile terrain for Roosevelt and liberal internationalist
factions of the capitalist class to combine Keynesian practice with forms of
worker control embodied in the Fordism.
So in the aftermath
of the two New Deal programs, in which Roosevelt’s progressive state became the
arbiter between corporations and labor, the American ruling class restored
people’s confidence in the capitalist system (Ferguson, 1995). By controlling the
excesses of Wall Street with finance and banking reforms, inflating
agricultural prices to compensate for lost farmer incomes, and granting more
collective bargaining rights to labor (at least their main industrial
organizations were accepted as equal negotiators on the table), the American
economy became robust. The stability pact, which incorporated labor unions as
junior partners in the postwar system, would be projected worldwide, as
interwar and intrawar economic developments elevated
the United States to the position of global leader of the Western world. Since
the ruling class was well aware that interwar instability came from a lack of
regulation among big capitalist economies, they put forth a plan at Bretton
Woods that aimed to internationalize the American domestic stability pact, as
well as further foster conditions for the extension of American industrial and
military power (Gill, 1988)
The New Deal and the
emergence of welfare states within the Western bloc was nothing other than what
Gramsci called passive revolution (Gramsci, 1971). In this new organization of
state power, the bourgeoisie, especially internationalist monopoly capital,
accepted some of the demands of the working class in order to neutralize the
revolutionary potential of its adversary. However, the capitalist character of
the relationships of production remained intact. In the Fordist compromise of
the 1950s and 1960s, trade unions largely accepted the supremacy of capital in
the work place and refrained from using their destructive potential as the
Fordist and Keynesian policies required mass consumption capability for the
mass production of commodities. That compromise provided rising real incomes to
workers within the limits of capitalism until 1970s.
Moreover, given the international
conditions of the postwar era with the Soviet Union a major industrial rival
and European economies in ruin, which consolidated fears of revolutionary
insurrections, capital had no choice but to prefer welfare capitalism to an
unstable mode of production. Certain sections of the ruling class learned from
the Great Depression and Keynesian polices that they could use the capitalist
state as a means to secure the long-term interest of the bourgeoisie as a
whole. The subordination of shortterm interests of
class factions like money capital was necessary. The most salient proof of this
passive revolution was the fierce anticommunist rhetoric espoused by the United
States and its Western allies after the war (Cox, 1987), (Rupert, 2000), (Gill,
1988). Even the American Federation of Labor (AFL)-CIO joined this crusade by
purging communist militants and supporting anticommunist “free trade unionism”
around the world in direct collaboration with the CIA. These changes in state
form and capitalist ideology were accompanied by a set of international
regulations that were drafted in Bretton Woods in 1944.
The deal that was
struck at Bretton woods in 1944 largely reflected the balance of power within
the world system, and especially among the different competing sections of
capital within the American ruling elite. The existence of British negotiators,
and Keynes at the table, colored the eventual agreements so that they were more
in line with the protectionist cause of Britain’s sphere of interests. Those
articles in the IMF agreement that gave flexibility to governments in domestic
policy, for example, allowed countries to devalue their currency in the face of
trade deficits at the expense of the stability of old gold standard days. Some
of the trade arrangements concerning preferential treatment of specific nations
are an indication of the interventionist strand of the postwar deal.
Bretton Woods first
stabilized international exchange rates by establishing 1 ounce of gold as
equal to U.S. $35. Since United States was the biggest creditor, it immunized
itself from speculative attacks by virtue of its massive gold reserves (Webb,
1995). Also parallel to the objectives of American hegemony, three postwar
institutions were created (Pastor, 1980). First, the International Monetary
Fund was established to help member nations solve their balance of payment
problems. The IMF was intended to be a lender of last resort in case of balance
of payment deficits, which made countries vulnerable to speculative attacks on
their currency. This provision was designed to guarantee domestic stability in
concerned nations since measures like devaluation and interest rate hikes would
create reductions in the purchasing power of the masses. The IMF lent money to
these deficit countries in order to stabilize transition periods. In addition
by installing a weighted voting system, the dominant capitalist powers gave
themselves crucial decision-making abilities, denying newly independent Third
World nations substantive influence within the institution. This obvious
dominance of capitalists in control of the IMF resulted in the exclusion of
communist countries from the Fund’s activities altogether (Heleiner,
1994), (Cohn, 2000).
Second, the World
Bank, founded in the aftermath of the World War II, was designed to provide
reconstruction and development finance to countries, especially for planned
projects rather than purely financial matters. The smaller nations and the
Eastern bloc showed more interest in the Bank because of its supposed priority
of supporting planned projects, which implied that it was relatively
independent from capitalist interests in the organization phase of projects.
However, the management of the World Bank and IMF has been generally determined
by the consensus of Western powers. The IMF’s executive directors are chosen
from Europe, while the World Bank’s presidents are usually American (Helleiner, 1994) (Van Dormael,
1978).
The General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) was the third institution drafted in Bretton Woods.
The GATT was designed to create a liberal international trade environment by
securing gradual mutual tariff reductions within the international system. As
one of the greatest obstacles to recovery before the war period was the
competitive nationalistic tariff increases by big powers, the postwar consensus
aimed to prevent the repetition of it. This tariff agreement can also be
interpreted as a concession to the more liberal minded parts of the bourgeoisie
for it’s acceptance of domestic policy priorities of
respective governments. For example, as a further stabilization of domestic
economies the Bretton Woods agreement put controls on capital movements to
eradicate the speculative tendencies of the international financial system.
Moreover controls on capital movements guaranteed steady tax revenue for
governments necessary to finance Keynesian policies. The welfare reforms that
constituted part of the hegemonic discourse of elites to entice trade unions
into postwar capitalist plans significantly depended on steady tax revenues.
Thus, allowing unfettered mobility to finance capital would have caused a
crisis within the structures of welfare state (Pijl,
1984).
In the wake of
instability that was created by the Allied victory, most European countries and
bourgeoisies felt threatened by the radicalization of working class movements,
as they still did not have the economic basis to support the new international
consensus around Fordist corporate liberalism. Some sections of the European
bourgeoisie even resisted this new accumulation style as it hindered colonial
policies. One of the basic conditions of Marshall Plan Aid to these countries
was to end their discriminatory trade practices in their colonial spheres as
dominant American capital wanted to penetrate these regions. A substantial part
of the Marshall Plan was designed to spur international demand for American
commodities and agricultural products. Harry Truman in his memoirs argued for
the necessity of raising the living standards for the people of Africa and Asia
to keep up the sustainability of capitalist production in core countries like
the United States (Pijl, 1984).
What American capital
wanted from Europeans was to create a flexible political environment so that
mass consumption, required by mass production of Fordist assembly lines
(including raising living standards for working class), and the gradual
liberalization of international trade would complement each other. However, the
political concessions given to the working class stopped short of endorsing any
encroachments on the prerogatives of private property. If we turn back to
Schmitter’s concept of corporatism he wrote: Corporatism can be defined as a
system of interest intermediation in which the constituent units are organized
into limited number of singular, compulsory, noncompetitive, hierarchically
ordered and functionally differentiated categories recognized or licensed (if
not created) by the state and granted a deliberate representational monopoly
within their respective categories in exchange for observing certain controls
in their selection of leaders and articulation of demands and supports (Quoted
in Panitch,1980:p 167).
The Roosevelt
administration’s New Deal policy and associated forms of Fordist social
relationships were emphasized as the prototype of this new order in Europe and
rest of the world. As argued above, the New Deal state in America was not a
radical break up from the old mode of production, rather it was a
reconfiguration of class interests within the state in the aftermath of the
Great Depression in favor of the liberal minded state-monopoly faction of the
bourgeoisie, which had attained a sound victory over finance capital’s
laissez-faire-style capitalism with the tremendous growth numbers of Fordism
and New Deal.
In order to preempt
and further reduce the resistance of European colonial interests among the
bourgeoisie and the more militant and skilled working class (who were adamant
to protect their power over production in the old guild-style organizations),
Truman used liberal European parties of Europe to pacify the former and the
AFL-CIO to disorient the latter. In France liberal parties of the Fourth
Republic gained power. Liberal leader Herriot took up many important positions
in the new parliament, and Rene Mayer of the Radical Party became the finance
minister, gaining strength against both the left and conservatives. This
processes culminated with the premiership of H. Queuille
from 1948 to 1949, who succeeded in carrying through the major monetary and
economic adjustments required by Marshall Plan. In Germany the liberal FDP had
important cabinet positions, especially in the ministry responsible for
Economic Cooperation until 1956. The German subsidiaries of U.S. firms and
their managers strongly supported Atlantic unity and liberal minded
legislation, as the Allied powers brought most of these liberals into major
trusteeship positions in postwar Germany. In Britain Churchill and Eden’s
return to power replaced conservative nationalist tendencies with liberal
internationalist ones within the British state. With the 1956 Suez debacle, the
old imperial yearnings of British conservatives shattered, thus consolidating
the liberal faction’s grip over the state. The corporate strategies of British
corporations such as Unilever, ICI, and Lloyd Bank’s followed the dominant
Atlantic pattern closely during those years. In Italy after the Liberal Party’s
inclusion within the government in 1948, textile capitalists and their
confederation’s head, A. de Micheli, undertook joint ventures with American
capital.
Major Italian private
steel firms’ endorsements of American style democracy contributed to the
liberalization of Italian politics. In the Netherlands and Belgium, liberal
parties, strongly supported by the United States, came to power with the agenda
of joining the Atlantic capitalist alliance (Pijl,
1984).
American efforts,
however, were not confined to liberal parties; the United States also worked
with Christian Democrats not only by boasting the positions of liberals in
those parties but also by creating a common front with these parties’ religious
bases against the “godless” communist threat. The second dimension of this
Atlantic alliance was to replicate the features of AFL-style collective
bargaining within Europe through deradicalizing the leftist tendencies of
European labor by incorporating them within the institutional structures of the
new corporatist framework.
The AFL started this
labor offensive from occupied Germany, as it was the easiest country to
influence, by creating labor groups that were outside the traditional idea of
workers’ councils in Germany. The major aim was to propagate the AFL’s version
of economistic trade unionism, which ultimately breaks with any class heritage
or perspective in dealing with employers. The aim was to increase productivity
and growth in a harmonious relationship with the business rather than to spur
an independent and conscious working class worldview among the workers. The
ICFTU (International Confederation of Free Trade Unions) was founded to counter
the influence of WFTU, which the U.S. perceived to be nothing more than a tool
of Soviet policy.
This American
offensive, complemented by the purge of so-called “communists” from the CIO in
the 1950s, tried to create a rift within the general labor confederation CGT in
France. After failing its first attempt, the AFL-CIO (unified after 1955)
eventually succeeded in infiltrating the Socialist party and union circles.
Avowed anticommunism accompanied by efforts to gain the trust of the French
working class on American foreign policy did not bring a majority to the
pro-American camp but deepened local divisions among the French trade union
movement, preventing it from becoming an anti-capitalist force. In Italy by
supporting Catholics, the AFL tried to divide the main trade union, CGIlL, but the fragmented nature of Italian politics
prevented further unification of pro-American forces beyond anti-communism. In
the Netherlands and Belgium, the main trade union leaders were already paid
agents of the CIA so penetrating them was relatively easier. The British labor
union TUC was under the influence of the Labor Party and immediately recognized
American leadership, especially organizing around journal “Socialist
Commentary”, which primarily propagated anti-communist left rhetoric in Britain
(Pijl, 1984), (Gill,1988).
Thus this entire
endeavor to control the European working class consolidated the concept of
Atlantic Fordism since by then the infrastructure of the main industries was
sufficiently prepared for the application of the mode of American-style
accumulation and industrial relations. In terms of corporatism most of these
labor unions were incorporated into the hegemonic bloc of Fordism by accepting
the predominance of business in workplace organization in exchange for economic
concessions such as rising living standards and welfare benefits from the
state. This working class adaptation of the separation of economic demands from
political objectives in reality impoverished the class perspective and the
power of labor; it also prepared the groundwork for the further attack on
labor’s social rights in the 1970s resulting from the multinational capital
offensive. That offensive aimed to “technocratize”
even economic issues, rendering them solvable by and understandable to only
so-called experts (Pijl, 1984).
These comprehensive
concepts of control, like Fordism and the welfare state, contained their own
contradictions. For example, banks had gotten the right to form large holdings,
and their taxation was stabilized in the United States (Gill, 1988). Dividends
from capital gains and tax deduction of ground rents from oil exploration
especially strengthened the hands of financial capital and oil and mineral
industries. Monetary controls on capital movements were relaxed as a complement
to the above.
In Europe the
conservatives who thought that the imperialism could lose control in the
periphery opposed Harry Truman’s aggressive support for decolonization. These
developments somewhat challenged Atlantic unity, as frictions heightened
between pro-U.S. sections of the European bourgeoisie and the factions that
wanted to protect their overseas imperialist interests. In that environment
London-based banks, which wanted to bypass the currency controls imposed by the
British government, attempted to create a Eurodollar market. This was as an
indication of the coming laissez faire offensive.
According to Pijl, this was a demonstration of industrial capital’s
weakening share of international trade vis-à-vis finance capital. These
divisions also prompted the CIA and corporations like Unilever to organize a
conference at Arnhem’s Bilderberg hotel to discuss important issues like
Western unity against Soviet Union and how to handle decolonization, but the
meeting could not reconcile the colonial interests of France and the
modernizing influence of American capital (Pijl,
1984), (Gill, 1990).
In the 1960s the
Kennedy administration sped up efforts to recover from special interest
dominated politics. In order to refresh the New Deal policies and reinvigorate
American industrial capital’s investment returns at home and in Europe, the
administration started another Atlantic unity offensive.
For example granting
the black population full citizenship rights not only solved the democratic
legitimacy problems of U.S elite but also facilitated the incorporation of a
potentially explosive social strata into the Fordist framework. Other programs
like the war on poverty and extensive social assistance packages were required
in order for the administration to be able to launch a more activist foreign
policy on the Cold War front and in the Third World’s newly independent states.
As financial markets increased their attacks on regulation through the
Eurodollar market and some parts of the European elite invested in American
bonds and other rent related instruments, productive industrial capital tried
to press the Kennedy administration to spur its fortunes, perhaps for the last
time before the great profitability crisis struck (Gill, 1990).
In the colonized
parts of the world, people who gained their independence from imperialism after
arduous struggles were, nevertheless, greatly affected by the structural and
cultural penetration of centuries-long Western intervention. Local leaders of
resistance movements mostly saw two alternative hegemonic paths when they
decided to embark on socioeconomic development. On the one hand, Soviet-style
socialism, with its impressive development record in a very short period of
time, was seen as a solution. On the other hand, by emphasizing the lack of
political democracy and the totalitarian nature of the Soviet model, some
factions embraced the idea of catching up with the West and aspired to become
like the United States by the end of the century. The crucial element in those
struggles was most of the leaders of African and Asian independence movements
were either nationalist or subscribed to different non-Marxist notions of
socialism, like Arab Socialism (Kaber, 1967), (Beinin, 2001).
Given the worldwide
balance of forces and the Soviet Unions’ tacit acceptance of Western backyards
in the periphery, exemplified by Stalinist concepts such as the necessity of
collaboration between the subordinated classes and national capitalists against
imperialism, independence movements focused more on the nationalist aspect of
liberation. Actually U.S president Truman also advised Third World countries to
adopt some form of nationalism as long as it kept them from direct Soviet
influence. So Truman’s four point program and U.S.S.R’s objectives regarding
newly independent territories complemented each other.
Also, according to
Robert Brenner, “between 1957 and 1965, manufacturing investment by majority
owned foreign affiliates of U.S companies in new plant and equipment overseas
grew at an astonishing annual average rate of 15.7 percent” (Brenner, 1998: p
55). Western involvement brought about a twisted corporatism, as it passed to
the periphery not the model of Fordist industrial relations but the Taylorist form. In mass production centers, largely the
orientation was assembling foreign produced parts by a group of skilled workers
who were incorporated into the domestic hegemonic project through recognition
of their social rights and trade unions. But the remaining layers, for example,
female workers or workers in service and agricultural sectors, lived under
conditions approximating slavery. In these sectors Taylorism and super-
exploitation were the organizing ideas. So unlike mass-based democracies of the
West, the peripheral corporatist arrangements generated authoritarian and
crisis prone political systems, since the adaptation of mass democracy could
jeopardize the fragile hegemony of domestic elites. In different parts of the
Third World, the more powerful industrial bourgeoisie could, at least in short
durations, increase the representation levels of subordinated classes to both
increase its legitimacy and mass consumption until another business cycle
struck their profits.
One can argue that
the Fordist compromise in the core was spread to the Third World elite in the
1960s through American projects like the Alliance for Progress, which aimed to
offer development assistance to strengthen Western influence and economic appeal
against the Soviet Union’s autarkic economic policies. But this seemingly
successful capitalist consensus on Fordism and its industrial organization
started to crack with the tendency of industrial profit to decline after 1965.
The result was global cutthroat competition and an ever growing U.S. balance of
payments deficit emanating from large defense and social expenditures (Gill,
1988).
German and Japanese
states and capitalists in turn enjoyed the protectionism that was financed by
an overvalued U.S. dollar, not only in an economic sense, but they were also
immune from large-scale defense expenditures by the virtue of positioning under
the American nuclear umbrella against the Soviet Union. On the economic side,
German and Japanese states provided direct financial support to their
respective capitalists, and corporatism connected the state, finance and
industrial capital, and labor unions to the issue of increasing productivity
and export oriented growth. Even in sales processes, German and Japanese bank
capital and state agencies supplied crucial financial and marketing information
to their fledging capital. On the labor front, these governments repressed
labor militancy with the help of American occupiers and increasingly suppressed
trade union demands by either using low-wage workers from countryside or
inviting skilled but cheap labor forces of Third World countries (except
Japan). As the U.S. international interest and strategy depended on increasing
the power of its allies, it opened its large domestic markets to German and
Japanese goods, while their capitalists benefited from isolated markets within
their borders. Technology transfer was another crucial part of the development
aid package that the United States offered to its allies. This was indeed a
crucial element as direct state aid to European and Japanese capital,
especially in manufacturing, created more flexible production lines within
these countries. The Germans and Japanese used this easy access to technology,
sponsored by the state, to their advantage in terms of cutting costs in
manufacturing lines. On the contrary, the United States only supported its
capital through Keynesian policies, stimulating aggregate demand by increasing
the money supply, especially through its massive military purchases. American
liberalism did not support European-style comprehensive state planning in
specific industries (Brenner, 1998). The direct result of those events and
policies was the massive fall in the profit rates of American manufacturers
between 1950-58. Under that period profits fell 41 percent. As wage increases
spurred higher production costs, the money supplied by the military-industrial
complex largely incurred inflationary costs to the economy. The early 1960s
offensive aimed at cutting labor costs and reducing productivity problems, only
slightly reinvigorated profits, and was not a long-term panacea to the problems
of American manufacturing.
While the GATT rounds
gradually eliminated high tariffs and other trade barriers, international
competition escalated among the industrial powers for new markets and raw
materials. The American manufacturing industry, which already had massive sunk
capital investments in fixed properties and a legacy of tight labor markets,
found it less attractive to completely renovate its capital investments as fast
as its overseas rivals. That fact, coupled with the oligopolistic behavior of
American firms in the domestic market, relatively reduced the profit margins of
new comers since large companies decided to stay in an established
manufacturing line as long as they attained a rate of return that could
compensate their sunk fixed capital investments. The necessary price increases
could not be transmitted to consumers as cut-throat international competition
from Europe and Japan already removed that option from consideration. As the
German and Japanese states created closer ties between banks and their
manufacturers to instigate export booms, for American finance capital, overseas
investments were more profitable than supporting domestic ventures, because the
dollar was strong vis-à-vis rival currencies. The situation was further
exacerbated by the tendency of American firms to invest overseas and sell their
goods to domestic markets as imports since they had weaker rivals and more
profitable lines in those distant markets. Finally, the American state’s
defense expenditure or military-related demand incentives did little to
increase productivity, because it bolstered neither the total capital
investment in the means of production due to the nature of its output nor the
total consumption of workers. However, it did comfort trade rivals of American
business by making them decrease their own military expenditures (Brenner,
1998) (Gill, 1990), (Pijl, 1984).
After 1965,
manufacturers worldwide, especially the Group of 7 economies, suffered from
significantly reduced profit margins. According to Robert Brenner, the decline
occurred because fledging Japanese and German industrial capital captured
considerable markets. Under normal conditions, these firms should have forced
unproductive rivals out of the market or diverted their resources into other
manufacturing lines or sectors of international economy. However as mentioned
above the sunk costs of fixed capital requires time for efficient returns. Most
of the obsolete producers stayed in their lines to at least recover their
circulating capital. This caused an immense crisis of over-capacity and
overproduction within world trade. Between 1965 and 1973, U.S. manufacturers
sustained a decline of more than 40 percent in the rate of return on their
capital stock. Moreover, efforts to recover profitability, such as the
sustained assault against unionization (unionization rates fall sharply after
1960s) and securing government support to correct the imbalances of
international trade terms (Nixon’s decision to opt out of the Bretton Woods
gold-dollar parity), further deteriorated the conditions for G-7 economies. By
massive dollar devaluation, U.S manufacturers simply exported the crisis to
German and Japanese manufacturers (Brenner, 1998).
The factors that
influenced postwar American hegemony can be summed up as follows: First, the
intensification of inter-capitalist competition, especially when cheaper
Japanese and German products started to capture the U.S. domestic market,
resulted in the erosion of the oligopolistic pricing power of U.S. companies
within their own territory. This was largely the result of U.S. cold war
policy, as successive administrations supported the development and
industrialization of allied countries.
Second, the widening
postwar social safety net and active use of macro policy to limit unemployment
placed constraints on the power of capital. These principles are embodied in
what John G. Ruggie called embedded liberalism, which
caused delays in capital’s response to international requirements of capitalist
competition. Third, after 1968 there was increased social discontent worldwide.
In the United States, this stemmed from the Vietnam War and civil rights
violations, while in the Third World it was partially rooted in the
increasingly populist (nationalist) discourses of elites. These developments,
coupled with the beginning of recession in the fourth quarter of 1969,
considerably constrained American geopolitical power not only to favorably
change the terms of international trade but also to successfully manipulate
international politics against the Soviet Union (Ruggie,1996) (Ikenberry,
2001).
The U.S. government’s
response to the domestic crisis of its firms was to pump up demand by injecting
money into the market either through defense expenditures or other government
procurement. As American companies could not increase their prices due to
international and domestic competition, and given the fact that investing and
creating additional capacity required time, the government’s fiscal policy
produced runaway inflation. While the U.S. was incurring huge budget deficits,
Germany and Japan accumulated huge budget surpluses, which contributed to the
financial imbalances within the system.
With Nixon’s decision
to opt out of the Bretton Woods’ gold/dollar parity, supported by American
capital’s massive offensive against unions and wage increases in the
manufacturing sector and the Federal Reserve’s anti-inflationary policies,
American capital tried to restore its position. Those measures temporarily
shifted the direction of money capital to the U.S. reduced the costs of U.S
manufacturers significantly in comparison to overseas rivals, and exported the
crisis to countries with overvalued currencies, in turn diminishing the
productivity and profitability of German and Japanese capital (Gill, 1988).
Finance capital’s
power and its position in the hegemonic bloc rose positively in the light of
these developments. The anti-inflationary policies of FED (Federal Reserve
Bank) (i.e, rising interest rates) provided finance
capital with opportunities for arbitrage between low-interest and high-interest
countries. Growing U.S. deficits and rising surpluses in Germany and Japan
created incentives for finance capital to launch massive speculative attacks,
as many countries could not defend fixed exchange rates with their diminishing
gold reserves. Also the non-manufacturing sector, such as services, largely
protected itself from international competition by preventing wage growth
within its domestic markets. Since the creation of Eurodollar markets, finance
capital also found a venue to bypass government controls on its foreign
investments. The last ditch attempts of governments to increase controls were
further overcome by creating offshore-banking institutions, which the United
States and United Kingdom condoned because they wanted to promote New York and
London as the main financial centers. The balancing of budgets was not
politically convenient in democracies, and thus politicians chose to finance
those deficits through debts. That means they have to concede more to the
finance capital in order to obtain necessary loans. From 1965 to 1973 financial
institutions within the G-7 initiated new mergers, thereby spreading their
interests within other sectors of the economy. Britain and the United States
were the first to free their finance capital from controls regarding the
holding activities of financial groups. The declining profitability in
manufacturing diverted manufacturing investments into the financial sector
also, as firms sought to restore their own position. Chase and J.P. Morgan,
whose profit share of international activities were 25 percent and 22 percent
respectively in 1969, increased their shares to 78 percent and 56 percent by
1976. In Europe financial firms, such as ABN Amro, Barclay, Deutsche Bank, and
the French Paribas, initiated mergers with productive sectors and their
American and Japanese counterparts to construct a new trilateral hegemonic
project to replace the old Keynesian-Fordist promises. As the 1973 oil crisis
deepened economic problems and further reduced manufacturing profits, the new
economically liberal era dawned, promoting individualism and orthodox
prescriptions of laissez faire capitalism.
As Robert Brenner
argued persuasively in his 1998 article, the bottlenecks that the capitalist
system confronted after 1973 initiated a major downturn within the capitalist
world, especially in G-7 economies. Since the Nixon administration’s decision
to abandon the Bretton Woods exchange system, governments, starting with the
United States and Britain, joined the corporate assault. While corporations
wanted to reduce real wage growth, governments applied pressure on the growth
of welfare expenses by cutting social expenditures. All these policies aimed to
eliminate the so-called inflexibility of labor markets, which anti-Keynesian
economists deemed to be the biggest hurdle to the recovery of profitability.
Nevertheless, the neoliberal prescriptions failed to spur a momentum to
profitability, especially in manufacturing.
First, the old
manufacturing firms decided to stay in business despite tight credit, a low
level of demand, and low level of profit. Under these conditions of inefficient
operation, these companies should have been forced out of manufacturing.
However, these established companies had intangible benefits from their lines
of production, such as sound relationships with consumers and markets. Their
circulating capital and fixed capital stock also sustained their production
against adverse conditions for a significant period of time.
Second, neoliberal
policies reduced aggregate demand overall in capitalist economies, which in
turn reduced the profitability chances of other production lines, namely they
prevented those companies from trying alternative sectors. The entrance of
Third World manufacturers into the basic sectors of manufacturing, such as
textiles, processed food, and commodities, largely intensified competition
levels among capitalist rivals. Increased competition further reduced the
chances for manufacturing to recover.
Third, Reagan and
Thatcher’s massive military expenditures and budget deficits created an
unprecedented growth of government debts to finance the deficits. In that
context finance capital supplied enormous amounts of money to make profits from
companies which were starved for capital investment and strained consumers who
are seeking to sustain their consumption levels. The striking point about these
debts, however, is that they did not actually create the conditions for a
massive overhaul of capital investment, the recovery of profitability, or a
general increase in aggregate demand. They largely saved big capitalist
economies from entering into a deep depression under the recessionary
conditions of the 1980s, essentially prolonging the life of low-profit, high
cost firms in manufacturing. The growth of general indebtedness around the
capitalist world not only strengthened the hand of money capital—through
speculative attacks on surplus and deficit countries’ currencies in a free
floating regime—but engendered a situation in which the eventual eradication of
overcapacity within capitalist manufacturing was postponed through this
artificial respiration (Brenner, 1998).
For example, most
Third World countries, as a result of neoliberal prescriptions and free
floating currencies, had to adopt higher interest rates in order to attract
foreign investors even though it drowned their domestic demand. However,
short-term speculative finance generally increased the deficits of these host
countries as most of them tried to balance their long-term deficits through
short-term debts from open markets. Then a vicious circle occurred in which
rising deficits provide conditions for the further currency devaluations and
render the country more vulnerable to speculative attacks. The IMF and World
Bank became the chief proponents of these neoliberal austerity packages. But as
governments cut their social expenditures, raised their interest rates,
liberalized, and privatized state industries deflationary tendencies emerged
and reduced overall demand.
Most manufacturing
giants preferred to downsize their workforce in unionized and largely regulated
areas of the world economy and transfer these production lines to deregulated
places whose docile and suppressed workforce was open to overexploitation. This
became a predominant strategy after 1970s, since neither national markets, in
profit levels, nor nationally unionized work forces were convenient for the
cut-throat competitive conditions of the neoliberal era. Capital sought to find
a new way in post-Fordist flexible production systems to restore its profit
rates. Below I will look at the nature of post-Fordist production and state
alliances within this framework.
The structural
constraints of nation-state system and regulated markets forced the dominant
sections of capital, first financial, then industrial, to initiate a complete
break with Fordist-Keynesianism, which embodied the historical gains of the
working class and the obstacles that created the tendency of falling profits in
the first place. Fordism symbolized relatively intact and fixed social
relationships of production (the controlling dimension). Homogeneous markets
for standardized mass consumption products and the concomitant division of
labor constellated around the nuclear family led to relatively predictable
patterns of social interactions. However, those stable patterns were already
under attack by the fiscal insolvency of the welfare state and the growing
resistance of capital to subsidize it (Aglietta,
1987).
In the post-Fordist,
flexible mode of accumulation, companies have integrated global points of
production and consumption into their balance sheets; they have started to be
an organic part of companies’ businesses in contrast to international trade of
the Fordist years in which the national regulation of accumulation was the
foremost priority. These developments were accompanied by a vast surge in
service sector employment and the emergence of new industrialized zones in
formerly underdeveloped regions of the planet. The increasing reliance on
part-time workers, flexible labor contracts, and growing competition among the
unskilled unemployed for fewer jobs were also part of the trend. The trend to
surpass national regulations put in place during the Fordist era pushed
companies to subcontract jobs in regulated spheres to informal firms with
nonunionized workforces and even to families and greatly changed the nature of
the employer-employee relationship. The consciousness of workers was easily
manipulated by those multi-faceted forms of exploitation. Capitalist wage-labor
intertwined with feudal patriarchies or coercion within the family with regard
to labor practices itself contributed to the disillusioned environment of
identity politics (Harvey, 1990).
Finance capital was
the first faction of capital to benefit from these conditions; it not only took
advantage of euro-dollar markets and other offshore banking institutions to
bypass nation-states but also it was innovative in finding solutions to the problem
of global accumulation. For example, those financial derivatives and associated
debt “products,” though complicated in nature, were used to create fictional
credit instruments to smooth out the recessionary tendencies of global markets
(Patomaki, 2001).
In the age of finance capital, David Harvey argues that creation of twenty-fourhour trading zones that connect global markets and
financial institutions was also a significant attempt on the part of the
capital to overcome the time/space problem in search of new profits. This
time/space compression synchronized the exploitation of the world labor force
and other resources with enormous speed. Electronic trading can shift millions
of dollars from one global production point to another in seconds, leaving the
subjects of those sudden economic shifts, populations, helpless. This
facilitates and quickens turnover rates of capital as companies in the
accelerated phase invent new products, whose consumption can be reduced to
hours or even minutes. Events or relatively short-lived consumer commodities
largely replaced investment in durable goods of Fordist era. In another
dimension the speed of accumulation and production rates of capital enormously
advantaged big capital over small business, as the processes required the up to
minute knowledge of financial and commodity markets (Harvey, 1990).
In order to stabilize
the new framework of those new relations of production, the dominant factions
of capital entered into new coalitions and constructed new forms of ideological
control around the globe after 1970s. Crystallizing with the Reagan and Thatcher
governments’ policies and the conservative surge within the Third World,
transnational liberalism found fertile terrain in the neoliberal state. The
table below from Harvey’s book summarized the sea change within the nature of
global capitalism since 1970s.
Thus as Robinson,
Gill, and Cox have argued, the neoliberal state has been a byproduct of
capitalism’s attempts to emancipate itself from the constraints of national
regulation and nationalistic ideological frameworks. Neo-Gramscian’s
do not perceive the state in a Weberian sense in which the state is reduced to
its administrative and coercive apparatus or its set of political institutions.
Notwithstanding the actual practice of state agencies and their powers, the
state is also a moment of class power relations, in the Marxist sense, which
has a dialectical unity with the actions of state institutions (Robinson,
2003). As Pjil demonstrated, the resurgence of money
capital and the emergence of finance capital as the dominant faction in the new
post-Fordist era have affected the structure of the nation-state. The consensus
around neoliberalism has been generally promoted by these transnational
classes, which incorporate some sections of the old Fordist welfare state while
radically transforming the nature and tasks of capitalist states (Pijl, 1984).
The Bank for
International Settlements, the WTO, G-7, OECD, EU, ASEAN, APEC, and NAFTA are
all examples of this process of transnationalization.
Every year world corporate, political, and intellectual leaders gather at the
Davos economic forum to discuss the problems of the global system. The
ideological loyalty of participants to the idea of global neoliberalism has
been more important than their territorial loyalties to their respective
nation-states. So through the reallocation of crucial decision-making powers to
those transnational institutions, global capitalism has shifted the function of
policymaking from the nation-state to supranational bodies. Readers should
avoid falling into a false dichotomy by perceiving the nation-state as external
to this process. As this chapter has explained, changes in the nature of class
alliances and the mode of production within national states provided the
terrain for transnationalization.
This process is continuously underway.
For example, when the
IMF imposes Washington consensus policies on Third World countries, those Third
World elites, in terms of education and shared social and economic values are
not very different from IMF and core country elites. The main aim of these
supranational institutions is, as Robinson has argued, to stabilize the social
relations of global capitalism in the absence of a global hegemon that can
provide collective goods to the systems actors (Robinson, 2003).
Neo-liberalism’s
reduction of political economy into technical language, its isolation of
economic decision-making bodies from popular pressure, for example central bank
autonomy, and separation of politics from economics, as though they are
ontologically distinct spheres, have largely resulted with what Bob Jessop
called the hollowing out of the national state. Nation-states have been
gradually becoming population control centers for global capitalism, as the
national capitals increasingly resist financing the social tasks of the Fordist
welfare state. The decaying infrastructure, education, and cultural framework
of these national social formations in the last three decades has also created
enemies of globalization. Nationalist factions of domestic capital have also
emerged, which resent their exclusion from the construction of a new global
hegemonic bloc. Increasingly there has been a surge of popular anger against
the “agentless” globalization trend. While these trends clearly demonstrate
that global capital has increasingly broken reciprocity with labor, population
control mechanisms of national borders and repressive state apparatuses,
coupled with twisted forms of production relations in the flexible mode of
accumulation, have still oppressed labor within the constraints of the
nation-state. The transnationalization of global
capital laid bare the growing objective existence of a global proletariat whose
consciousness is distorted by the multi-faceted identity politics of our
postmodern era (Jessop, 2002) (Robinson, 2005).
The concept of
postmodern used here refers to what mainstream academia discussed the cultural
and economic changes of late twentieth century. Since capital must compete to
reduce turnover time of their returns from investment through time/space
compression, relatively fixed identities, perceptions, and relationships of
modernity or Fordism have been unraveled. The ever growing uncertainty and
abstract individualism have replaced previous identities, which ideologically
fits well with the agenda of global capital that aims to create a radical
rupture with old Fordist forms of collective survival.
The contraction of
the state from role in education, industry, and social welfare exacerbates the
burden of local administrators who primarily aim to increase the competitive
edge of their local industries and sectors in the global market place. Local resources
were never enough to replace the tasks of national government. In that context
populations who are marginalized from formal political institutions seek to
identify themselves with alternative concepts. Frederick Jameson and Harvey
have argued that the capitalist market actually celebrates these attempts at
diversity, which in terms of cultural production enlarge the exploitable area
(Jameson, 1991) (Harvey, 1990).
In an ideological
sense, the postmodern current in contemporary capitalism, by arguing for the
equality of diverse cultural forms and ways of knowing and doing, and the idea
of emancipation from the modernity’s meta-narratives, has served two distinct
purposes. First, it legitimizes the current human condition by disarming
historical explanations and refusing their explanatory power as
meta-narratives, and secondly through postmodernist judgmental relativism, it
justified the neoliberal state’s depoliticizing of the public sphere.
Postmodernism’s agnosticism towards any historical explanation and
transformative project about society has achieved the implicit recognition,
without problematizing it, of the existent relationships of the capitalist
system in which the dominant power of the emerging transnational bourgeoisie
tries to create a world in its own image. To borrow some thoughts from the
Communist Manifesto, two of Karl Marx’s assertions regarding the human
condition in the capitalist system clearly explain why the ideologies like
postmodernism and identity politics are so popular against so-called
meta-narratives. Marx wrote, after defining the constant revolutionizing role
of the bourgeoisie in order to survive in competitive production: “All that is
solid melts into air, and all that is holy is profaned, and man is at last
compelled to face with sober senses, his real conditions of life, and his
relations with his kind” (Marx, 1993: p 46). However, in the context of
uncertain, rapidly changing, and seemingly uncontrollable social forces, an
individual human being cannot grasp the real nature of what is ephemeral and
what is structural with a completely open mind.
Thus, identity
politics and postmodernist trends have resurfaced; they are the weight of those
“dead generations” in a time of rapid change and uncertainty. Since my project
is to explain the rise of political Islam, the emergence of identity politics
with neoliberal state forms and class alliances is crucially important.
The resurgence of
identity politics is the lack of a material basis for a sound hegemonic project
on the part of world capitalism today. It stems not only from the fact that the
dominant faction, finance capital, is the most short-sighted faction of capital,
but in absence of projects like those associated with the Keynesian welfare
state transnational liberalism has engendered very reactionary and opportunist
class alliances for the shortterm success of this new
capitalist project. Starting from Reagan and the Republicans’ increasing
flirtation with Christian right-wing elements within the United States, global
capitalist classes have relied on the help of many right-wing forces in the
Middle East, including the Taliban, Osama Bin Laden, and the Saudi royal
family.
Neo-Liberalism in the Middle East and Political Islam
The rise of
neoliberal forms of state and policy practices within the Middle East began
with the enormous legitimacy crisis of nationalist and Arab socialist regimes
immediately after the 1967 defeat by Israel. Not only did import-substitution
and social welfare policies in countries like Egypt, Tunisia, Morocco, and
Jordan increase their budget deficits, but the political bankruptcy of these
regimes in the face of the massive Arab defeat in 1967 further undermined
support among ordinary Arab citizens.
The 1970s witnessed,
starting with Anwar Sadat’s pro-Western policies in Egypt, a regional overhaul of
traditional class alliances based on nationalism and Arab socialism. Sadat got
rid of the Soviet advisers of the Nasser era and implicitly supported religious
groups like the Muslim Brotherhood against the leftists and Nasserists
in Egypt. Increasingly the economic volatility of period forced more Arab
leaders to abandon the basic socioeconomic priorities of their respective
states. As most of these states began to encourage the formation of a new class
of financiers, middleman, and importers, these new classes, who wanted to
integrate their national economy into the global economy, tried to break with
the previous compromises with the working classes and peasants. This process is
still underway, but the pressures from internal and global sources rose as the
Thatcher and Reagan governments made the policy prescriptions of the Washington
consensus the new economic dogma (Beinin, 2001).
In that nexus between
the neoliberal ascension in the West and the legitimacy crisis of nationalism
and socialism in the region, new elites and old state cadres found common
interests with the West in the wake of the 1973 oil crisis. Oil prices and
OPEC’s daring attitude during the embargo deepened the economic bottlenecks of
already crisisridden Keynesian–Fordist systems in the
West. The abundance of petro-dollars after 1973
largely benefited oil-rich countries, such as Saudi Arabia, the United Arab
Emirates, Iran, and Iraq. These petro-dollars
provided enormous profit opportunities to Western banks and their Middle
Eastern partners. This was also a period of economic deregulation of
international finance. Between 1973 and 1981 oil prices increased from $2.00 a
barrel to $40.50, resulting in massive construction and development projects in
countries like Saudi Arabia, UAE, Bahrain, Iran, and Iraq. The oil-poor
countries in the region used this environment to send their unemployed urban
poor and some skilled workers into the Gulf region to diminish the effects of
massive population pressure on industry and economy.
However, the
relatively smoothing effects of the oil-boom on the regional economy was
reversed with the 1980s debt defaults of the region’s countries and the strict
monetary policies of Western powers during Reagan’s early years, coupled with
the drop in oil prices in 1985-86 (Beinin, 2001), (Gause, 1994).
The oil-boom,
contrary to OPEC’s initial argument against the West, consolidated the
integration of Middle Eastern economies into the global capitalist system, as
most countries accepted IMF structural adjustment conditions with the
unraveling of oil prices after 1981. Even in countries that do not have oil,
the decrease of labor and agricultural export demand from the Gulf region
sharply constrained their revenues and increased their unemployment, which
naturally resulted in massive budget deficits and IMF bail outs. Structural
adjustment policies forced governments to undertake the liberalization of
markets, privatization of state industries, massive cuts in social spending,
roll back of working class gains, especially in terms of real wage increases,
and curtailment of agricultural development projects that had the potential to
contain the enormous influx of rural migrants to cities. Those policies created
a power vacuum in welfare provision and thus strengthened the hand of Islamic
groups as they criticized Arab nationalism and socialism’s failures in
administering these societies. State social policies abetted in this process as
the neo-liberal bloc wanted to eradicate the gains of the working class and
associated leftist forms of collective organizations. While some Islamists are
fiercely anti- Western and anti-Modern, their acceptance of the rules of
commerce and the profit system made them a potential junior partner for
neoliberal elites (Beinin, 2001).In terms of statistical results of neoliberal
policies in the region, in Egypt real wages fell 40 percent from 1985 to 1995.
Income distribution worsened; from 1982 to 1991 the Gini coefficient rose from
0.32 to 0.38 in the country. The segment of the population under the poverty
line rose 30 percent from 1985 to 1990. In Tunisia, the share of the poorest 20
percent of the population in total consumption stagnated around 5-6 percent
from 1976 to 1986.
In Turkey after the
decade of implementing Washington consensus policies, real wages in the public
sector declined by 39 percent and civil service wages declined 13.5 percent.
Overall the share of wages in the GDP from 1980 to 1990 dropped from 39 percent
to 23 percent. Even in authoritarian regimes such as Syria and Iraq, which did
not have agreements with the IMF, the real wages were suppressed and the
unionization rates around the Middle East continue to fell after 1980s. The
World Bank in 1995 in a rare moment of honesty accepted the fact that decades
long neoliberal policies could not increase the living standards of workers in
the region. (Beinin, 2001), (Halliday, 2002)
In terms of political
and military strategic alliances, the 1970s corresponded to the increasing
insecurity of two powers in the region. The United States was plagued with its
defeat in Vietnam and the loss of some key struggles in Latin America and Africa
against nationalists or the left, the rising domestic economic problems of
stagflation, the Iranian revolution, and the Soviet invasion of Afghanistan.
Meanwhile, Saudi Arabia was threatened by the Iranian Islamic revolution and
Shiite interpretation of Islam.
The geopolitical
interests of these two countries revolved around anti-communism and anti-Shiite
rhetoric, as the United States also saw the Iranian revolution as a problem for
its interests in the region. This spurred a much closer alliance between these
two countries. Before the oil embargo, an American oil company, Aramco, was the
only explorer of oil in Saudi Arabia. The Saudi elite actually tried to oppose
OPEC price hikes in order to not to undermine global economic growth, which the
Saudi elite was dependent upon. In that context in the Afghan trap for the
Soviets, the Saudis financed the resistance and religious propaganda, while
Pakistanis performed intelligence gathering, and the CIA supplied the weapons
and training. The Soviet occupation created the perfect opportunity not only
for political Islamists like Osama bin Laden. (Gause, 1994).
After that close
collaboration in Afghanistan, the Saudis further intensified their efforts to
disseminate Wahhabi-style Sunni orthodoxy around the Muslim world and in
Western Islamic communities. The Saudi education ministry allocated billions of
dollars from oil revenues to pay the expenses religious preachers and to
disseminate religious educational materials with the orders of King Faisal.
Another of King Faisal’s efforts to spread his ideology consisted of the
creation of Islamic financial systems through banking practices that were
acceptable to the rules of Sharia.
With petro-dollars coming from Western countries, the Saudi’s
launched their Islamic Development Bank initiative both to control the
diversion of funds within the Middle East from oil revenues and to create an
Islamic alternative to secular institutions like the Arab League. Since
interest income is shunned by most Sunni Muslims, these Islamic financial
alternatives provided opportunities for Saudi Arabia and also Western banks
that dealt with investing oil revenues on behalf of Arab governments (Henry and
Wilson (eds), 2004).
First, Islamic
financing shifted the emphasis from interest-income-based conventional banking
to the equity-financing-based (non-interest) investments. These Islamic funds
approached the small business and the middle-class bourgeoisie who had a hard
time acquiring large amounts of credit from established conventional financial
institutions. In conventional banking the deposits of a bank are invested
without too much personal trust or monitoring activity, which somewhat lessen
the costs. On the other hand, in Islamic equity financing, the relationship
between the bank and the borrower is that of the partners in a business.
Islamic banks are promised a share of the profits of borrower’s commercial
operation, in case of losses the bank has to bear the consequences. In this
type of banking, the most important issue is the trust between two sides,
complemented by a lengthy process of monitoring and high costs associated with
that process.
Inadvertently, under
those circumstances the IMF’s structural adjustment prescriptions, such as
reducing the state bureaucracy, increasing transparency in balance sheets of
companies, and privatization, are economically more beneficial to Islamic
financial institutions than to their conventional counterparts, since less
bureaucracy and more transparency reduce the costs of the lengthy monitoring
process between the creditor and the borrower (Kahf
in Henry and Wilson (eds), 2004), (Warde in Henry and Wilson (eds),2004) .
These kinds of
investments with small and middle-class businessmen started a process in which
mostly neglected rural and marginal entrepreneurial groups could finally find
low-cost credit channels, while the Muslim poor, who despised interest-based
banking, also find a new venue for their otherwise dormant savings. From 1973
to the 1990s, there was a proliferation of Islamic banking institutions in the
Middle East and North Africa. These Islamic groups benefited not only from IMF
packages but also from the political climate of the period. With the declining
influence of populist nationalism, governments suppressed the left, while
politicians competed to be seen as more Islamic than others, in part by
providing tax incentives and special privileges to Islamic groups. For the
worldwide transfer of funds, the Islamic traditional system of hawala, which
uses a courier for carrying funds from one place to another, transformed into
new forms, as Islamic financing became popular among immigrants in oil-rich
Gulf States and Western countries. Saudi-style Sunni orthodoxy influenced
immigrant workers in the Gulf by embedding them into its local cultural
framework. Meanwhile, immigrants in the West were controlled by the Saudi
financing of their mosques and social projects. From the late 1970s to 1990s,
the success of these Islamic financial institutions correspondingly began to
change the political perceptions of pious Muslims from the Sayyid Qutb's understanding of the total political overthrow of infidel
governments to a more reformist, gradual Islamization of every sphere of life
starting from economy. The devout Muslim underclass became better educated
through the Islamic sponsorships as a result of the convenient political and
economic climate. This perspective forced Islamic groups to compete with
secular institutions in education and to place its loyal members in the
important political positions of states (Halliday, 1996) (Henry in Henry and
Wilson (eds), 2004).
IMF policies and
economic liberalism are congruent with the interests of the Islamic
entrepreneurial class. Global capitalism’s market niches and career
opportunities have incorporated the Islamic opposition into its global
framework. Even after the events of September 11 most of Muslim funds have been
either invested in more mature Western markets or directed by Western fund
managers. Their criteria of investment and location choices more closely
resemble that of conventional banks, emphasizing political and social
stability, commercial risk assessment, and rates of return rather than the
religiosity of the respective country. And fledging Islamic bourgeoisies also
push their political representatives to accept the norms of Western financial
and political institutions.
This does not mean,
however, there is no opposition, radical groups like Al-Qaeda have become
increasingly bitter in terms of their hostility to this Islamic-Western
alliance or gradual incorporation of Islamic movements within this so-called
infidel system. Since the implosion of the Soviet Union in 1991, when there
ceased to be a communist enemy, the marginalized Islamic opposition diverted
its anger toward Muslim governments and their Western allies (Warde in Henry
and Wilson (eds), 2004), (Halliday, 2002).
Islam as a political
ideology accepts the basic tenets of capitalism, such as the sanctity of
private property, validity of debt contracts, and the legitimacy of commercial
profits. Given the fact that Islamists lack any credible democratic and
emancipatory political program, excluded sects could not provide sustainable
alternatives. The Islamist opposition, generally, in line with postmodern
identity politics, argues for the overthrow of an unjust and corrupt system and
its replacement with a state that is governed solely by the rules of Islam.
They saw that modern man started to idolize parties, nationalism, socialism,
luxurious commodities, instead of god, resulting in the erosion of Islamic
social values. This cultural and ideological critique, emphasizing the personal
and political mistakes of Muslim ruling elites, ironically fell into the trap
of neoliberalism’s separation of economics from politics. Hence, in ignoring
the coalescence of interest between neoliberal economics and Islamic
entrepreneurs, the main lines of Islamist critique of the modern order lack a
substantial understanding of the dialectic unity in reproduction of the
socioeconomic processes that they criticize.
We now will explore
Turkish political Islam as a microcosm of these general developments regarding
political Islam and capitalism.
For updates
click homepage here