By
Eric Vandenbroeck and co-workers
US documents released
in the context of the Holocaust Era Records Act between 8 and 10 years ago show
among others that from 1937 to 1940 a dozen experts in U.S. financial agencies
analyzed Japan's balance of payments, gold production and reserves, scrap gold
collection, liquidation of foreign investments, and other financial data. They
also predicted when Japan would be bankrupt and have to stop the war in China,
always six to eighteen months in the future. It was a comforting thought to
policymakers, but the analyses were wrong.
From 1938 to the summer of 1940 the Bank of Japan secretly accumulated
$160 million in the New York agency of the Yokohama Specie Bank. It began with
funds removed from London. It was a sum equal to three years' oil purchases
from the U.S. The YSB did not report the deposits, as required by law. Bank
examiners discovered the fraud in August 1940. Japan raced to withdraw the
money during the first half of 1941. The fraud accelerated thinking in
Washington toward a dollar freeze, instead of commodity embargos, as the most
deadly sanction. The freeze order was drafted in March 1941. As is well known,
It was imposed on 26 July 1941 when Japan occupied southern Indochina. After
the freeze, Japanese diplomats and agents proposed many ideas to unfreeze
dollars in order to reopen trade. Dean Acheson, the effective manager of the
freeze policy, rejected them all. In August 1941 the Japanese government,
through Mitsui, made an extraordinary offer to barter $60 million of silk for
$60 million of US commodities, mainly oil. Barter would not require unfreezing
dollars, they thought. Strangely, they chose as spokesman a
Roosevelt-hating lawyer named Raoul Desvernine.
Acheson and Vice President Wallace rejected the scheme on 15 September, about
the time the Japanese government was reaching a decision for war. Furthermore
features of the prewar situation from records that were not classified but that
are omitted from other history books, thus there are a large number of
vulnerability studies, of Japan's foreign trade written in April 1941 by
committees of trade experts of U.S. agencies under the direction of the Export
Control Administration. Reviewing the oil and tanker situation in both Japan
and the U.S. for example one will here find that FDR blamed an imaginary
shortage of gasoline in America as a reason for the freeze of Japan. There was
no shortage despite the loan of 20% of US tankers to Britain. Two-thirds of
Japan's dollar earnings were due to exports of raw silk to America. (When the
war began in Europe all other currencies became blocked and inconvertible.) The
Great Depression and rayon substitution destroyed the silk dress industry.
After 1930 nearly all Japan's silk went for American women's stockings, which
was a strong market despite the Depression. On 15 May 1939, however, DuPont
introduced nylon stockings at the New York Worlds
Fair. They were a great success. By 1941 nylons gained 30% of the market, and
we're on track to 100% in 1943 if no war. The market loss of $100 million per
year would have been a disaster for Japan if it had not gone to war. Yet what
the following case study furthermore shows is that Roosevelt's idea of a
financial siege of Japan in fact backfired by exacerbating rather than defusing
Japan's aggression. And for sure the attack on Pearl Harbor was not the result
of a deliberate Roosevelt strategy (as right-wing conspiracy theorists claim),
but a Roosevelt miscalculation.
U.S.Exports to Japan 1939 (in Millions of Dollars)
U.S.Exports to Japan 1940 (in Millions of Dollars)
U.S.Exports to Japan 1941 (in Millions of Dollars)
The American
perception of Japan's economic and financial vulnerability dated back to a time
thirty-five years before Pearl Harbor. President Theodore Roosevelt grew
concerned after the victory over Russia in 1905 that Japan would seek to
dominate China in contravention of the U.S. Open Door policy, which championed
independence and free trade for China. Japan would perceive that policy, and
U.S. bases in the Philippines and Hawaii, as barriers to building an empire.
Roosevelt asked the U.S. Navy for a plan to fight Japan, if and when necessary.
The result, War Plan Orange, was fundamentally an economic strategy in both
origins and outcomes. (Japan was code-named Orange, the United States Blue.)
The godfathers of the plan, Admirals George Dewey and Alfred Thayer Mahan, had
served as young officers enforcing the Union's Anaconda Plan against the
Confederacy, an "island" vulnerable to economic blockade. They and
later disciples in the War Plans Division of the Navy demonstrated a fierce
mindset favoring vigorous action, a mindset echoed by civilian bureaucrats who
advocated a nonviolent economic and financial "war" against Japan in
the crisis years before Pearl Harbor.
While U.S. military
planners assumed Japan's war aims would be limited --a surprise attack, victory
in a naval battle, and a negotiated peace ceding dominance of East Asia--their
aim was a crushing defeat of the enemy, and aim demanded by an aroused public.
They understood that Japan, an island nation poor in natural resources,
depended on overseas trade for the sinews of war and its very economic life.
The Japanese Empire produced food enough, but industrialization and conquests
led to the voracious needs of metals and fuels. The planners designed a
strategy of siege. After initial losses, Blue forces would fight back island by
island, sink the enemy fleet, seize bases near Japan, starve it of vital
imports, and ultimately force it to capitulate. Japan's financial destitution
would be ensured by "coercive pressure" on world lenders to deny
funds such as Wall Street provided during the Russo-Japanese War. Plans rang
with confidence that the United States could enforce "final and complete
commercial isolation" (1906), leading to "eventual impoverishment and
exhaustion" (1911) and "in the end ... economic ruin" (1920). As
airpower came of age, the bombing of industry and transportation intensified
the siege plan. In 1941 Plan Orange morphed into global Plan Rainbow Five, and
in 1942-45 it was executed in most major respects. The Pacific war culminated
in unconditional surrender after the devastation of Japan's economy, including,
in the end, the deployment of atomic bombs.
In the 1930s
peaceable internationalist governments in Tokyo gave way to military-dominated
regimes. The anticipated violations of the Open Door unfolded in the invasion
of China and designs against colonies of the Western powers. The helplessness
of Japan, if isolated economically and financially, evolved into an axiom at a
time when the U.S. government was averse to fighting a war. When the national
policy to deter Japanese aggression took root, the United States gradually
deployed its vast economic and financial powers to strangle Japan by means
other than ships and bombs. It was a Plan Orange strategy in peacetime. The
story now turns to the U.S. strategy of achieving the nation's foreign policy
aims, without combat, by bankrupting Japan.
When Japan invaded
China on 7 July 1937, U.S. government financial experts reckoned the aggressor
could not wage a long war because it lacked hard currency to purchase essential
commodities abroad. As Herbert Feis, the economic adviser of the State Department,
wrote, "Warfare requires many vital raw materials which Japan does not
possess at all or in sufficient quantities, and which must be purchased with
foreign exchange." Therefore, the "ability of Japan to carry on a
protracted war depends ultimately upon her actual and potential foreign
exchange resources." (Herbert Feis, Economic Adviser, "Japan's
Ultimate Foreign Exchange Resources," 20 September 1937, Box 21, File
Japan Foreign Exchange Position, OASIA.)
And as early as 1935,
it sought to regulate its position as the world's most important supplier of
materials for war, it was in the summer of 1941 the United States decided to
deploy its most powerful economic sanction against Japan, dollar freezing. The
first steps, taken at a time when Japan was not yet an aggressor in China, was
aimed at keeping the United States from being drawn into another foreign war.
Later steps were taken by so-called voluntary means and by executive orders to
ensure that the nation's exports did not support Japanese aggression in China.
In fact, sanctioning to impose a nation's will on others in peacetime was also,
not a novel concept, as it was based on international law governing trade
relations among sovereign states laid down by the European jurists Hugo Grotius
and Emeric de Vattel in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries.
Thus in the autumn of
1937 Franklin Delano Roosevelt brooded about deterring foreign military
dictatorships from attacking peaceful nations. On 5 October, thirteen weeks
after Japan invaded China, the president delivered his famous
"quarantine" speech. Likening the spreading aggressions to epidemic
disease, he suggested that law-abiding countries ought to quarantine the
aggressors. When pressed by reporters, he denied that he meant economic
sanctions, calling sanctions "a terrible word to use." "There
are," he said, "a lot of methods in the world that have never been
tried yet."! Roosevelt was not sure what he meant until December after
Japanese bombers sank a U.S. gunboat in China. He turned to his energetic
secretary of the treasury, Henry Morgenthau Jr., for a "modern"
weapon to wield against Japan. Treasury experts unearthed the perfect device: a
relic of the First World War known as Section 5(b) of the Trading with the
Enemy Act (TWEA), a single paragraph that empowered the president to paralyze
dollars owned by foreign countries, whether enemy or not. Denial of U.S.
dollars, a key reserve currency of the world and indispensable to Japan for
waging war, could dissuade Japan from belligerence. That surviving section of
the act had arisen from an obscure spat in 1917 between government agencies
that foreshadowed the bureaucratic grasping for power in Washington during
1937-41 as the United States groped toward invoking its great financial powers
to render Japan effectively bankrupt in the world.
And finally, the
first months of 1941 then, marked a turning point in the will of the United
States to advance from a patchwork of export restrictions to full-blooded
financial warfare against Japan. A spurt of work from January through March
established the nature of the financial punishment it would mete out when the
time came. Above all, that the levers of control would be manipulated not by
learned economists and banking technicians, nor by moderate diplomats seeking
bargaining leverage, but by truculent lawyers determined to show Japan no
mercy.
In common English
usage, "bankruptcy" is a synonym for "impoverishment."
Japan was cast into international bankruptcy, a condition of absolute
illiquidity, by the U.S. financial weapon. The chokehold of the relentless
freeze rendered its dollars and gold worthless for national survival. It was a
strange sort of bankruptcy. Japan's reserve of gold and dollars exceeded $200
million in late 1941, enough to buy, for example, four years of U.S. oil at
pre-freeze shipment rates, yet it was rendered useless. Thereafter Japan piled
$60 million of new gold and $15 million of silver into the useless reserve
every year until it suspended mining of precious metals in 1944. Japan had
invested in gold mines, collected gold ornaments, and nurtured dollar-earning
exports.1 It had husbanded its reserve for future purchases of resources for
its war economy, inflicting "the curse of gold" on its people by a
"wholesale attack on the standard of living." At the end of the war,
although the economy was in a shambles, the government of Japan was awash in
gold amounting to twice its hoard in 1941. After the surrender, the gold and
silver in the Bank of Japan and other government vaults were sequestered by
MacArthur's occupation forces. As to Japan's frozen dollars, they were never returned.2
A contemporary
journalist summed it up. He could not have known that for four years, U.S.
Treasury and Federal Reserve analysts had predicted Japan would soon exhaust
its assets and necessarily abandon its aggressive policies. However, he wrote,
"Japanese leaders exerted every possible effort to avoid this outcome.
They succeeded... Gold production was stimulated A vast foreign exchange
reserve was maintained." Although U.S. forecasts of empty vaults proved
false, Japan was plunged into the international bankruptcy they predicted
because of a stroke of a pen in Washington.3 Two views, one American and one
Japanese, illustrate the attitudes about Japan's bankruptcy on the eve of war.
When Dean Acheson
arrived at the State Department in January 1941 he rediscovered the prodigious
powers of Section 5(b) of the 1917 Trading with the Enemy Act. He and
colleagues of like mind promoted its deployment against Japan, then twisted a
cautious squeeze designed "to bring Japan to its senses, not its
knees" into strangulation. Acheson, an officer of the department charged
with peaceful solutions through diplomacy, boasted to Cordell Hull on 22
November 1941 that financial crippling had proven far more devastating to Japan
than embargoes. The freeze administrators thwarted Japan from removing its
dollars from U.S. control as it had been doing for a year. Their actions
slashed U.S. exports to zero despite Japan's valid export licenses for oil, and
other licenses it would have been entitled to for cotton, lumber, and
foodstuffs. Nor could Japan pay the mineral-rich nations of North and South
America or the Dutch Indies, which demanded dollars, while the sterling bloc
joined in the freeze. U.S. markets abruptly closed to Japan. Washington refused
to allow Japanese trading companies to receive dollars, even if paid into their
blocked accounts, hastening the ascendancy of nylon, which devastated silk
farmers and demolished Japan's largest renewable flow of dollars.4
U.S.Forecasts of Japan's International "Bankrupty,"
1937-1941
In Japanese eyes, the
bankruptcy was a lethal threat, an assault on the nation's very existence.
After the war, Koichi Kido, lord keeper of the privy seal and adviser to
Emperor Hirohito, delivered an eloquent statement through his American defense
counsel, William Logan Jr., before the International Military Tribunal for the
Far East. (Kido was found guilty of war crimes and sentenced to life
imprisonment but was released in 1955.) Kido styled his defense "Japan Was
Provoked into a War of Self-Defense." Allied charges of war crimes defined
aggression as "a first or unprovoked attack or act of hostility."
Kido argued that strangling an island nation dependent on foreign resources was
a method of warfare more drastic than physical force because it aimed at
undermining national morale and the well-being of the entire population through
starvation. A nation, he concluded, had the right to decide when the economic
and financial blockade was an act of war that placed its survival in jeopardy.
Kido thereby harked back to the dawn of international law three centuries
earlier when jurists held that refusal to sell to another nation might well be
a valid casus belli under extraordinary circumstances such as starvation. The
defense added, "We know of no parallel case in history where an economic
blockade ... was enforced on such a vast scale with such deliberate,
premeditated, and coordinated precision... Responsible leaders at that time
sincerely and honestly believe[d] that Japan's national existence was at stake."
Because sanctions "threatened Japan's very existence and if continued
would have destroyed her," the "first blow was not struck at Pearl
Harbor." Indeed, Lojan continued, the "Pacific War was not a war of
aggression by Japan. It was a war of self defense and
self preservation."5
The OSS Document.
Unfortunately for
Japan, its leaders chose a war that brought upon it far more economic
devastation than any sanctions, along with great loss of life and untold
misery. Although struggling along under bankruptcy without going to war was a
dreary prospect, a third course was open to Japan: renouncing imperial
aggression in return for thawing of the freeze. One may wonder, what if Japan
had endured the freeze long enough to ascertain that Germany could not win and
had then abandoned the Axis, perhaps even joined the Allied side as it had in
1914? It would have prospered mightily by selling ships, machinery, and other
goods to the Allies. It would have emerged after the war as the strongest
regional power, with a world-class navy, an overflowing treasury, and a zeal
for industrial modernization, just as colonial empires in Asia were crumbling.
It might have shored up China against communism. A cooperative Japanese
commercial "empire" in East Asia, economically buoyant and trading
internationally on a grand scale a generation sooner, could have changed the
course of history in the twentieth century and beyond.
Arthur B. Hersey
titled his study for the Office of Strategic Services and the Department of
State "The Place of Foreign Trade in the Japanese Economy; an analysis of
the external trade of Japan proper between 1930 and 1943 focusing on possible
or probable postwar development." He comprehensively analyzed Japan's
external trade with both the yen bloc and the rest of the world in three
representative prewar years: 1930, 1936, and, to a lesser extent, 1938.6 His
goal was to outline a possible range of conditions of Japan's economy about
five years after the end of World War II to assist U.S. planners contemplating
post-surrender and occupation policies. The methodology was complex. To link
actual past to hypothetical future years Hersey converted physical units
(pounds, bales, square yards, calories, etc.) to a common denominator of
"constant yen," a proxy for physical units that also allowed him to
adjust erratic prices of internationally traded goods into more comparable
units.7
During the war many
economists expected a return of the global Depression after a brief postwar
boom. Hersey believed Japan's future in international trade to be especially
bleak. Its appetite for imports of minerals, industrial crops, machinery, and
even foodstuffs was almost unbounded. But its capacity to import would be
limited to the hard currency it could earn from exporting goods and services
and from gold mining. (He considered foreign loans unlikely.) In the 1930s
Japanese exports had expanded rapidly, but the benefits to the people had been
circumscribed for several reasons. A rising share of exports went to the yen
bloc, which could neither pay in hard currency nor deliver the most needed
commodities. While foreign countries erected barriers against Japanese goods,
the terms of trade (relative world prices) worsened after 1930. No foreign
loans were available due to disorganized financial markets in America and
Europe and active discouragement of lenders by those governments because of
Japan's aggression.
"The core of the
analysis," Hersey wrote, was a classification of Japan's imports
(typically 90 percent raw and semi-processed materials and foods and 10 percent
manufactures) into two categories: commodities required by factories that
manufactured products for export and commodities for final consumption within
Japan. The latter, labeled "retained imports," comprising 59 to 68
percent of all imports in the 1930s, contributed directly to the standard of
living. Another 25 percent of imports were materials for processing and resale
abroad, primarily raw cotton for textiles, wood pulp and salt for rayon, and
metals, chemicals, and fuels for other manufactures. A final 8 percent of
imports were offsets to exports of a similar nature, swapped, in effect, because
Japan both bought and sold in various grades and processed forms, wheat, sugar,
fish, coal, and fertilizer.8 Japan's greatest dilemma in the 1930s, Hersey
believed, had been deterioration of the "barter terms of trade," that
is, weak export prices and high import prices. Japan had to run harder to stay
in the same place internationally. For consistency, he recast the data into
indexes of "constant yen" at 1930 terms of trade. (He also calculated
1936 and 1938 terms of trade although they were of less relevance to his
conclusions.) Hersey selected 1930 as a "best case" year, similar to
the relatively prosperous 1920s, and the last equilibrium year of Japan's
international trade before the turmoil of world depression, yen devaluation, the
Manchurian adventure, and foreign trade discrimination. In 1930 Japan's upscale
products enjoyed high prices abroad, notably raw silk and silk fabrics, premium
seafood, fine pottery, and other consumer luxuries, while prices of raw cotton
and most other imported agricultural and forestry products were low. (Japan did
not yet import oil, metals, or minerals on a large scale in 1930, and not much
machinery.)9
A terms-of-trade
index is not the same as the familiar domestic price index. It is a ratio of
relative prices, that is, an export price index divided by an import price
index. Hersey calculated data for twenty internationally traded product classes
that he aggregated into eight groups: food; fertilizer and fodder; coal and
petroleum; metals and minerals; cotton, wool, and pulp for rayon; lumber and
paper pulp; and manufactured goods. He assigned to the terms of trade in 1930
an arbitrary index number of 100. The index for any other year, actual or
predicted, was that year's export price index divided by its import price
index. A resulting index above 100 meant a favorable trend for Japan and vice
versa for numbers below 100. Although any prediction was "pure
guesswork," Hersey admitted, a postwar Japan enjoying 1930 terms of trade
could fare adequately in the world, though not richly. "It is
doubtful," he opined, "whether Japan's terms of trade will under any
circumstances be more favorable than they were in the 1920s and 1930."
Hersey examined the
improvements of the Japanese standard of living before the war. Economists had
been awed by a surge of retained imports-79 percent higher in 1936 and 86
percent higher in 1938 compared with 1930but the benefit to ordinary Japanese
families was somewhat illusory. Yen devaluation, worsening terms of trade, and
a massive switch to importing and stockpiling of industrial and strategic goods
left the rise of retained imports for the benefit of the public at only 14
percent, barely more than population growth of 9 and 12 percent respectively
since 1930. Yet the Japanese standard of living had undeniably improved, by
about 10 percent per capita. Food consumption per capita was thought to be
unchanged; the rising population was fed from rising domestic farm output
through intensive fertilization. Gains in nonfood goods and services ranged
from 20 percent to more than 30 percent per capita. As with food, the gains
were mostly achieved by surges in production from domestic resources, notably
chemicals, electrical energy, and paper, and by the effect of rayon pulp (10
percent of textiles cost) substituting for raw cotton (50 percent of textile
cost). The experience implied that if postwar Japan could import consumer needs
for its populace at the 1930 rate in real terms per capita, reduction of the
standard of living would be tolerable, although disappointing for a population
used to improving conditions.10
For his "highly
tentative" postwar models of trade and living standards Hersey adopted the
hypothetical year" 1950" to represent a date a few years after the
war when physical reconstruction would be largely completed, production of most
domestic-sourced goods recovered, and crop yields normal. Population growth was
a crucial assumption. Japan's population had risen steadily at about 1 million
per year, from 64.4 million in 1930 to 72 million in 1938. Expecting
continuation of that rate, Hersey expected a population increase to 81 or 82
million in "1950," after adjusting for war casualties and
repatriation of Japanese émigrés from Asia.11 For a country that historically
found difficulty in feeding itself, millions of extra mouths would intensify the
dilemma of maintaining living standards in the face of weakened exports. Three
adjustments have been made here to adapt Hersey's data from "1950" to
represent Japan in, say, 1942, under a freeze but not at war with the Allies.
First, the population differences between the periods of seven to eight million
people are neutralized by converting trade to per capita values. Second, yen
are converted to dollars at appropriate exchange rates. Third, his eight
commodity groups are simplified into two: consumer commodities and others.
Japan's postwar
future was clouded by an anticipated vicious cycle of trade: uncertain markets,
adverse prices, and technological changes (notably the substitution of nylon,
reducing raw silk exports by an assumed 50 percent)12 resulting in a shortage
of hard currency to buy raw materials for factories that produced for export.
The uncertainties were profound. Rather than guess at world appetite for
Japan's specialized goods, Hersey found it easier and surer to calculate
imports essential for the survival of an impoverished populace. He, therefore,
set imports as the independent variable and assumed two levels of
"retained" and other imports. He then "reverse engineered"
his models to determine the exports necessary to fund the purchasing abroad.
Japan's exporting capability became the dependent variable. Hersey developed
two scenarios of the Japanese standard of living in "1950" by
arbitrarily assuming two levels of nutrition, expressed as daily calories per
person, which set an upper limit on non-food imports. Case A assumed the 2,250
calories prevailing in 1930, which had not increased much if any in the
following ten years. Assuming, however, that Japan's capacity to harvest crops
and fish had topped out by 1941, a larger share of its limited postwar earnings
would necessarily have to pay for imported food, fertilizer, and fishing boat
fuel. Imports of materials for clothing, shelter, and infrastructure would have
to be severely constrained by government priority rules, leaving little or
nothing for other consumer goods such as foodstuff varieties. The procedure
resulted in reduced postwar living standards of 25 to 33 percent depending on
the details assumed.13
Case B envisioned a
horrendous outcome for the Japanese people because of an exporting capacity so
enfeebled that not even basic nourishment and health could be maintained.
Hersey arbitrarily assumed a 20 percent reduction in nutrition below Case A, to
1,800 calories per person per day. Food and fertilizer needs would overwhelm
other import priorities. Only minor imports could be financed for other
consumer needs and urgent infrastructure. Retained imports per capita would
slump 67 percent below 1930.14 Hersey also calculated terms of trade for 1936,
the last peacetime year and a "worst case" year for Japan. Raw silk
prices had fallen disastrously. Textiles and other wares were restricted by
U.S. tariffs and quotas and by British imperial preference. Although exports of
chemicals and mechanical products-bicycles, sewing machines, industrial
machinery-held up better, Japan mostly sold them to the empire for yen.
Meanwhile, prices of
imported commodities were propped up by dominant suppliers such as U.S.
government supports of cotton. (Strategic metals and fuels remained relatively
cheap but were minor items of import before the war in China.) Relative to a
1930 index of 100, export prices in 1936 dropped to 95 whereas import prices
soared to 129. Japan then had to sell 33 percent more goods to buy the same
basket of imports. Because Hersey assumed the value of other imports as equal
to Japan's residual buying power after meeting food and fertilizer needs, the
large difference between 1930 and 1936 terms of trade dictated a necessity of
much larger exports, but did not alter his Case A and B models of
"1950." For example, Case A, calibrated to the 1936 terms of trade,
required 55 percent more exports versus the 1930 terms of trade model, $1.62
billion versus $1.05 billion, to achieve the same standard of living
established by Hersey's assumptions. (Hersey did not itemize exports in detail
as he did for imports because of extreme uncertainty over the products Japan
could sell, and to which countries, after the war.) Despite Japanese censorship
of data from 1936 onward, Hersey calculated a somewhat improved 1938 terms of
trade index but did not rely on it because distortions caused by the war in
China, commodity stockpiling, and a renewed U.S. depression that lowered the
cost of Japanese imports rendered it irrelevant to his vision of
"1950."15
As indicated above,
Japan's de facto bankruptcy proved a crucial factor in the failure of
negotiations for a peaceful settlement with the United States. The diplomatic
maneuverings of 1940-41 have been exhaustively described in documents, memoirs,
diaries, interviews, postwar investigations, and war crimes trials.16 Thus we
briefly summarize the events, focusing on the significance of the dollar
freeze. U.S. resentment against Japanese aggressions began with the seizure of
Manchuria in 1931 and accelerated when Japan assaulted China in 1937. The'
country initially reacted with diplomatic scolding’s, aid to China, and
embargoing exports of a few arms-related products. In 1940 tensions grew acute
when Japan signed the Tripartite Pact with Germany and Italy whereby the three
powers pledged to assist each other in wars, under certain circumstances. The
United States, inching toward war in the Atlantic through pro-British policies,
grew concerned that it might have to fight Japan as well. Negotiations for a settlement
of tensions began in earnest in April 1941. All discussions were conducted in
Washington between Ambassador Kichisaburo Nomura
(assisted after 15 November by special envoy Saburo Kurusu) and Secretary of
State Cordell Hull. The Japanese diplomats also met directly with President
Roosevelt, and occasionally with civilian and naval officials Nomura new
personally.
Other U.S. officials
played relatively minor roles.17 Hull advanced four "principles" for
Asia: respect for the territory and sovereignty of all nations, noninterference
in their internal affairs, equal commercial opportunity, and maintenance of the
status quo in the Pacific-the principles established by the Nine Power Treaty
of 1922. For Japan the main stumbling block was surrendering its decade of
conquests by withdrawing from Indochina and China, perhaps even from Manchuria.
In Japanese eyes a retreat would mean giving up any possibility of gain from a
war that had cost two hundred thousand dead soldiers, required huge outlays of
national treasure, and caused economic hardships for its people. The United
States further demanded assurances that Japan would renounce the Tripartite
Pact, or at least refrain from fighting it as an ally of Hitler. To prod Japan,
Washington embarked on three programs: arms and financial aid to China, a
buildup of forces at Pearl Harbor and in the Philippines, and barring exports
of commodities needed for its own defense.
The Japanese position
was, simply, resistance to Hull's proposals: no U.S. interference in
China-Japan affairs, no military withdrawals from occupied territories,
maintaining ties with Germany, and continuing trade with the United States. In
1941 events in Europe emboldened Japanese leaders. Hitler's attack on Russia on
22 June quelled the army's fears of a Soviet attack on the empire, and it
joined the navy in favoring a war to seize the resources of western colonies in
Asia. On 24 July, Japan, having coerced Vichy France, occupied southern
Indochina, triggering the U.S. freezing orders two days later and those of the
Allies soon after. After 26 July 1941 Japan's priority shifted to demanding an
end of the dollar freeze, or at least an easing so that deliveries of oil and
perhaps other strategic commodities might resume. At first, Tokyo phrased the
aim in generalities while its representatives in the United States searched for
loopholes. In August banking and consular officials petitioned for financial licenses
to pay for two shiploads of oil and probed the possibilities of paying with
dollars or gold held outside the frozen accounts. They were rebuffed at every
turn by the Foreign Funds Control Committee dominated by Dean Acheson.
Early in August Prime
Minister Prince Fumimaro Konoe launched an initiative
to meet with President Roosevelt personally, perhaps in Hawaii or Alaska, in
what later generations would call a summit meeting. To placate the generals and
admirals, Foreign Minister Teijiro Toyoda drafted
demands that the United States halt reinforcement of the Southwest Pacific,
mediate a peace settlement in China (a euphemism for abandoning aid to Chiang
Kai-shek), and restore normal commercial relations (a euphemism for ending the
freeze). In return Japan offered not to advance beyond Indochina and to
withdraw troops from China when the war ended at some vague future date. FDR
was intrigued but the State Department deemed the tradeoffs unacceptable,
especially because Japan refused to start evacuating promptly. The United
States declined the summit offer.
Japanese military and
naval leaders moved forward with plans to launch a war before the year was out.
On 6 September 1941 an imperial conference agreed to make a decision during the
first ten days of October about war against the United States, Britain, and the
Dutch Indies (a deadline gradually moved back to 29 November) unless Japan's
demands were met.3 On 18 September Acheson disclosed that the United States had
rejected Japan's last-ditch barter scheme of oil for silk. Mobilizing for an
attack began in earnest in Tokyo in the second half of the month. Nevertheless,
Toyoda wished to test other avenues of negotiation. The deadlock between the
war hawks on one hand and Konoe and Toyoda, who favored some troop withdrawals,
on the other hand, led to the fall of Konoe and his replacement as prime
minister by General Hideki Tojo on 17 October. Last-chance diplomacy passed to
a new foreign minister, Shigenori Togo.
Japanese agents had
continued to poke about desultorily for token financial licenses for oil or
minor freeze-evading transactions, without success. On 24 October, however,
Acheson told Counselor Tsutomo Nishiyama that the
looming insolvency of the Yokohama Specie Bank in New York, where Japan had
mobilized its dollars-a bank failure engineered by the U.S. government's
barring the bank from collecting money for silk delivered to the United States
before the freeze-would permanently lock up Japan's main holding of blocked
dollars. It was clear that oil cargoes would never sail. This casting away of
hope immediately preceded Tokyo's decision to demand financial relief, explicit
in time and very substantial in amount, countered by American musings of barter
concessions much below Japanese needs.
As resource
stockpiles dwindled, and with the military's reluctant consent, Togo proposed
"Plan A," an offer reciting kinder words about free trade in China
but standing firm on the Axis pact and rejecting troop withdrawals for
twenty-five years. As expected, Hull rebuffed it. Togo followed with "Plan
an interim truce. Japan would evacuate Indochina if the United States kept its
nose out of China, resumed trade promptly at pre-freeze levels, supplied oil in
abundance, and prodded the Dutch to supply more.19 The army insisted on
amending Plan B so that "the United States will promise to supply Japan
with the petroleum it needs." On 14 November the generals defined their
terms:
The United States
must sell a tonnage of oil equivalent to 42 million barrels per year (converted
here at 7 barrels per metric ton), including 10.5 million barrels of avgas, and
ensure another 14 million barrels from the East Indies. If the Dutch did not
agree, Japan would occupy the Indies. If the United States did not comply one
week after signing an agreement, the war would begin. Togo and Tojo scaled-down
the extravagant demands to 28 million barrels of U.S. oil, still a wildly
improbable figure 34 percent greater than the annual rate of U.S. sales in
January-July 1941. The amount was 259 percent greater than the 7.8 million
barrel annual quota based on 1935-36 that Washington had contemplated in August
for possible trade resumption. Avgas had been effectively embargoed since
December 1939. Nomura did not present the exorbitant demand because Hull's
response to Togo's first plan intervened.20
In November special
ambassador Saburo Kurusu arrived to assist Nomura, whose English was not the
best. As presented to Hull on 20 November, Plan B proposed evacuation of
Indochina, American noninterference in China matters, restoring pre-freeze
trade, including an undefined volume of oil, and helping obtain Indies
resources. Considering the plan "preposterous," Hull pondered a
response, urged by the military services to buy time for defense preparations
and by China and England not to go soft.6 On 18 October Hull had mused to Lord
Halifax, the British ambassador, about a minor swap of silk for cotton-not
oil-in exchange for a promise of a status quo in the Pacific. Anxious to avoid
a rupture, the Japanese envoys suggested another humble accommodation: small
quantities of U.S. rice and oil for Japan, far less than its full requirements,
with guarantees that none would go to its armed forces. Hull was willing to
think about it. Roosevelt informed Winston Churchill that the United States
might thaw the freeze slightly on quasi-barter terms, strictly for civilian
goods, for a three-month trial. The United States would license exports of food
products, ships' bunker fuel, pharmaceuticals, raw cotton worth up to six
hundred thousand dollars per month, and some petroleum for civilian needs while
encouraging the Dutch to supply more. Yet the United States would not unfreeze
Japan's dollars. Instead, it would buy Japanese products, two-thirds of which
was to be raw silk-about 5 percent of the pre-freeze rate of silk purchases-just
sufficient to finance the U.S. exports and to service Japanese bonds owned by
Americans.7 But the gesture, overtaken by the onrushing crisis, was never
offered to Japan. For six crucial days in November Hull played with notions of
a modus vivendi ("manner of living"), a standstill of three months
during which Japan would abandon southern Indochina, limit forces in the north,
and commence peace discussions with China. In return, the United States would
unfreeze some Japanese dollars and resume some exports, although export
controls in effect "for reasons of national defense" would remain. It
would encourage the British and Dutch to act similarly. Between 20 and 26
November, Hull reviewed a slew of proposals and modifications from administration
officials that watered down his proposal. Acheson's boastful report of the
excellent results of the financial freeze arrived on his desk. By 24 November
Hull's draft conceded a barter-type exchange of raw silk for oil and other
goods, amounts not specified, but no release of blocked dollars.
The eviscerated modus
vivendi was never offered to the Japanese. Allied scouting planes spotted a
troop convoy heading for Thailand and Malaya. Landings there were sure to
provoke war. On 26 November Hull's definitive response, approved by FDR,
retreated all the way back to stiff-necked demands for the four principles and
unlinking from Germany. Tojo deemed it an ultimatum.23 When six Japanese
aircraft carriers sorties from the Kurile Islands, Washington sent a war
warning to Pearl Harbor and other bases. An imperial conference of 1 December
gave up on negotiations and decided irretrievably that the empire would attack.
On 4 December the southern invasion force sailed for Malaya from Hainan Island.
On the sixth Roosevelt made a futile personal appeal for peace to Emperor
Hirohito. On 7 December Japan attacked Pearl Harbor. The two nations were at
war.
Japan Sources of Dollars, Actual, 1939-1940, and
Projected, 1941-1943
Japan: Retained Imports per Capita, 1930s and
"1950" Projections
Sources Including for Further Research.
The focus of this case
study is the United States' financial and economic sanctions against Japan
before Pearl Harbor, reconstructed primarily from official U.S. sources. Many
histories have been written about the run-up to the Pacific war, largely by
diplomatic historians, understandably in view of the centrality of the
Department of State in U.S.-Japanese negotiations and that department's
voluminous, well-organized files, which were declassified long ago, some as
early as 1943, supplemented by forty volumes of congressional hearings of 1946
about Pearl Harbor and precursor events.35
Not until 1996 did
the National Archives, at the prompting of a U.S. interagency group on Nazi
assets, declassify and make more readily available the worldwide papers of the
Treasury Department's Office of the Assistant Secretary of International
Affairs, established on 25 March 1938 and directed by Harry Dexter White.36
These records contain a trove of U.S. assessments of Japan's financial
problems, and U.S. proposals to exploit them, that have not appeared in other
histories. A similar wealth of information is in the records, first opened to
the public in 1996-97, of the Division of International Finance of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve system, primarily from 1935 to 1955. The
Federal Reserve Bank of New York voluntarily sent to the National Archives
those of its records "that relate to the activity in accounts for foreign
governments" in the same era.37 The files of the U.S. Alien Property
Custodian, which include the 1880-1942 records of Japanese bank branches in the
United States seized in 1941, we're closed until fifty years after the seizure
to researchers lacking special permission and were inconveniently located until
transferred to the National Archives II in 1995-96 and "bulk
declassified." The records of the Tariff Commission (now the U.S.
International Trade Commission), with a wealth of studies on specific Japanese
products, were open but not properly described and arranged until 1992.4 The
planning records of the Administrator of Export Control, the office that led the
drive for sanctions against Japan during the crucial months of September 1940
to May 1941, were difficult for researchers to use until recently, when they
were rearranged and a finding aid was prepared at the National Archives. That
office was subsumed in September 1941 into the vast wartime bureaucracy of the
Foreign Economic Administration, which in turn was reorganized three or four
times during the war. Its boxed records extend 3,817 cubic feet and weigh
seventy-five tons. A comprehensive catalog of all international records of the
era, which are mostly located at National Archives II in College Park,
Maryland, was completed in 1999 under the direction of Greg Bradsher and is
available online at http://www.archives.gov/research/ holocaust/finding-aid.
The main Japanese
sources are the excellent historical data published in bilingual tables by the
Japan Statistical Association, and Japanese commercial and diplomatic studies
published in English. Most of Japan's official records of 1931 to 1945 were burned
in the two-week interval between the surrender and the occupation in 1945 in
anticipation of war crimes trials. However, economic information for the last
prewar decade was reconstructed in detail and published by the U.S. Strategic
Bombing Survey and by investigators of the Supreme Commander of the Allied
Powers during the postwar occupation. Japanese financial and trade statistics
are usually presented for fiscal years beginning I April, so that, for example,
"1940" means the twelve months beginning 1 April 1940 and ending 31
March 1941. U.S. statistics are usually given for calendar years, making some
comparisons awkward. Physical trade units are stated herein U.S. measures such
as ounces, tons, or yards, or occasionally in metric measures. Some Japanese
figures have been converted from metric units or the ancient weights and
measures then used in trade.
Money figures are stated
in U.S. dollars, the dominant world currency then and now. The 1935-41 dollar
was worth about $10 in 2007 dollars if measured by an average of U.S. prices of
goods, or about $25 if measured by average U.S. wages. In exchange markets, the
yen was worth 49 to 50 cents from 1899 until devalued on 14 December 1931. It
dipped as low as 20 cents in 1932-33, then stabilized at 28.3 cents until 24
October 1939, when it was devalued to 23.4 cents. There was no organized
exchange market after 25 July 1941; fragmentary trading in China suggests that
in late 1941 the yen's gray market value was much lower, perhaps II or 12
cents.5 After devastating wartime and postwar inflation, the yen was stabilized
at 0.28 cents (360 per dollar). It subsequently has risen to almost I cent (l00
per dollar). The U.S. economy is roughly 150 times larger than in 1935-40 in
unadjusted dollars and about 10 times larger adjusted for price inflation. The
Japanese economy is about 500 times larger in unadjusted U.S. dollars and about
50 times larger adjusted for U.S. inflation. The prewar Japanese economy was
about 8 percent of the size of the American. In 2006 it was about 40 percent as
large. Japanese foreign trade is now about seven hundred times greater in
nominal value, $1.1 trillion versus $1.5 billion before the war, of which half
was within the "yen bloc." (Both figures are unadjusted for
inflation.) To grasp the relative significance in twenty-first-century terms of
$100 million in 1941, a very large fraction of Japan's international liquidity
at the time, the reader may wish to multiply by a factor of one thousand.
As seen above, the
United States forced Japan into international bankruptcy to deter its
aggression after Washington experts confidently predicted that the war in China
would bankrupt Japan. However, the United States did not know the Japanese
government had a huge cache of dollars fraudulently hidden in New York. Once
discovered, Japan scrambled to extract the money. But, in July 1941 President
Roosevelt invoked a long-forgotten clause of the Trading with the Enemy Act of
1917 to freeze Japan s dollars and forbade it to sell its hoard of gold to the
U.S. Treasury, the only open gold market after 1939. Roosevelt s temporary
gambit to bring Japan to its senses, not its knees, was thwarted, however, by
opportunistic bureaucrats. Dean Acheson, his handpicked administrator, slyly
maneuvered to deny Japan the dollars needed to buy oil and other resources for
war and for economic survival. So it is to the oil issue that we will turn to in part two.
1. In March 1941 the
Bank of Japan reported $117 million of gold in its vaults. Mine production
through July was about $20 million. Another $23 million is attributed so scrap
gold purchases, residual holdings in the Gold Fund Special Account and gold held
by other government agencies assumed from postwar data, minus industrial use.
In February 1941 the FRBNY had estimated that Japan held about $205 million of
gold, an exaggeration probably due to an older statement of the Bank of Japan
and overestimating gold production. Liquid dollar assets of the Yokohama Specie
Bank and other Japanese banks in the United States were about $40 million as
reported by the Office of Alien Property Custodian, more or less depending on
settlements of domestic liabilities ultimately allowed by the APC. Just before
the freeze virtually all strategic products except oil had been embargoed, but
Japan probably could not have purchased more than the recent $50 million of
U.S. oil (annual rate) due to tanker shortages. Purchases of nonstrategic
civilian products from America, some subject to licensing but likely to be
allowed due to abundance such as cotton, lumber, pulp, phosphate, foodstuffs,
pharmaceuticals, and some chemicals, had been about $25 million per year.
Against this potential $75 million of U.S. supplies, Japan was exporting $150
million to the United States (although the $100 million of raw silk was sure to
decline due to nylon's inroads). Purchases from other dollar countries were
curtailed by American and British preemptive buying of raw materials. As Kurt
Bloch, a reporter for the Far Eastern Survey, noted, "Japan's financial
difficulty abroad is no longer finding means of paying for foreign goods, but
rather finding foreign goods for which available means of payment can be used .
. . . At present, Japan's gold problem may not differ greatly from that of the
United States," an ironic statement because the United States had no need
of gold for international transactions as all nations would gladly have accepted
unlimited amounts of dollars. BB, Memorandum to the President, 5 August 1939.
Kurt Bloch, "Japan on Her Own," Far Eastern Survey, 3 November
1941,244-49.
2. In 1945 an
accounting submitted to the occupation forces reported that the Bank of Japan,
the mint, and other government agencies held approximately $461 million in gold
bullion and coin, $134 million of which was said to be held on earmark for the
account of Thailand and French Indochina for goods purchased from them during
the war. Government agencies also held $49 million in silver bullion and coins
and $4 million in currencies, primarily U.S. and British. The Yokohama Specie
Bank reported its overseas branches owned $10 million in U.S. dollars and $4
million in sterling, which of course had been frozen, $20 million of Swiss,
Swedish, and Portuguese currency accounts, and minor holdings of South American
currency accounts. The government also held $28 million (prewar value) of
German marks, yen, military yen, and local currencies of the colonies and of
occupied China and conquered areas, nominally worth hundreds of millions of
dollars but all of dubious value. Jenkins to I. S. Friedman and Coe, Gold Bullion
and Other Foreign Exchange Assets in Japan, 16 October 1945; Division of
Monetary Research, Tokyo Reports on gold, silver, platinum, currency, etc.,
owned by Japanese Government or Bank of Japan, I November 1945, File Japan
Foreign Exchange Position; Survey of the Gold Fund Special Account, c. August
1945; Tenenbaum to Friedman, Japanese Gold Production and Operation, 2 January
1946; J. Tenenbaum to Jenkins, Foreign Exchange Assets of the Yokohama Specie
Bank, I March 1946, Box 20, File Japan Banks and Banking, vol. I, OASIA.
3. Kurt Bloch,
"Japan on Her Own."Far Eastern Survey, 3
November 1941, 244-49. ---. "Japan's Problem Reversed." Far Eastern
Survey, 30 June 1941, 135-36.
4. Acheson to
Secretary of State, Present Effect of the Freezing Control in the Economic
Control as Exercised Upon Japan, 22 November 1941, FRUS, 1941,4:903-4.
5. R. John Pritchard,
commentator International Military Tribunal for the Far East, The Tokyo Major
War Crimes Trial: The Records of the International Military Tribunal for the
Far East (New York: Edward Mellen Press, 1998), 90:43159-62.
6. OCL, Place of
Foreign Trade, includes vol. I, pt. I, xvii, 1-158, issued 29 August 1946; vol.
I, pt. 2, 159-362, issued September 1946; and vol. 2 (statistical summary and
charts) xii, 1-128, issued January 1946. The ass was the ancestor of the Central
Intelligence Agency, established in 1947. William W. Lockwood, an economics
professor and author on Japan's economy, called it "a valuable study"
as late as 1954. Lockwood, Economic Development of Japan, 314. Jerome Cohen, a
professor of economics at the City College of New York, criticized the study
because it did not address the motivations for prewar Japanese trade-control
measures and thus "hinders an attempt to understand the problem as the
Japanese then saw it." Cohen, Japan's Economy, 12n27. Lockwood and Cohen
had access to 1937-41 data after the war that was unavailable to Hersey until
nearly the end of the study. Cohen's point is irrelevant for applying the study
to this chapter, which is intended as a speculation on how U.S. authorities
might have evaluated the impact of the dollar freeze on Japan if continued for
a few years.
7. OCL, Place of
Foreign Trade, vol. 1, pt. 1, iii.
8. Ibid., iv; vol. 1,
pt. 2, tables II-32 to II-34.
9. Ibid., vol. 1, pt.
1, iii; 11-21.
10. Ibid., 2-21.
11. Ibid., 110-11.
12. Ibid., 121.
13. Ibid., 43-66,
91-97, 109-145; vol. 1, pt. 2 177-81,205-12,231-33,254-63,272, 294-98, 308-10,
344-45, 352-59.
14. Ibid., vol. 1,
pt. 1,61-66, 114-15, 134-37, 143, app. 145-48, 152-53, tables 1-20, 1-21, 1-22;
vol. 1, pt. 2,177-81,208-12,231-33,254-64,272-74,294-98, 305-6, 309-10, 319,
322, 327-28, 336-37, 339, 341, 344-45, 348-49, 352-59.
15. Ibid., vol. 1,
pt. 1,67-87.
16. The U.S. Library
of Congress lists 115 books in English under "Pearl Harbor Attack,"
several dealing with the diplomatic and military preludes rather than the
attack itself (and a few espousing conspiracy theories). The principal
published documentary sources are FRUS, 1941, vol. 5; FRUS Japan; Congress,
Joint Committee on the Investigation of the Investigation of the Pearl Harbor
Attack, Hearings; and Defense Department, The "Magic" Background of
Pearl Harbor (Washington, D.C.: GPO, 1978). General works include Cordell Hull,
The Memoirs of Cordell Hull (New York: Macmillan, 1948); Feis, Road to Pearl
Harbor; Langer and Gleason, Undeclared War; Roberta Wohlstetter,
Pearl Harbor: Warning and Decision (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford Uni'(ersity Press, 1962); Dorothy Borg and Shumpei
Okamato, eds., Pearl Harbor as History: Japanese
American Relations 1931-1941, Studies of the East Asia Institute (New York:
Columbia University Press, 1973); Gordon W Prange with Donald M. Goldstein and
Katherine V Dillon, At Dawn We Slept: The Untold Story of Pearl Harbor (New
York: Viking, 1991); and Akira lriye, Pearl Harbor
and the Coming of the Pacific War (Boston: Bedford/St. Martin's, 1999). Works
that focus on the freeze and embargo in the negotiations include Utley, Going
to War with Japan; Barnhart, Japan Prepares; and Worth, No Choice but War. On
the Japanese side, see Morley, Final Confrontation; and Goldstein and Dillon,
Pacific War Papers, 136-234.
17. State Department
officers contributed advice, but Ambassador Grew in Tokyo was relegated to
incidental adviser and message carrier. Neither the secretaries of war and the
navy nor their uniformed chiefs, who tended to favor a softer line to gain time
for building up defenses, participated in direct negotiations, nor did other
cabinet-level officials, although some operated as advisers and go-betweens.
Consultations within the government were eclectic, ranging from sideline
discussions to full cabinet meetings. Intelligence agencies provided Roosevelt,
Hull, and a very few others with deciphered messages between Tokyo and its
ambassadors. Historians have differed on whether code breaking helped U.S.
negotiators or hindered them due to misunderstandings and poor translations. In
Japan, Prime Minister Prince Fumimaro Konoe was an
expansionist. Shortly before the freeze the foreign ministry passed from the
quirky, pro-Axis Yosuke Matsuoka to the relatively moderate Admiral Teijiro Toyoda who was more wiling
to negotiate. However, the Army and Navy held the balance of power because a
general and an admiral served as mandatory members of the cabinet so either
could bring down a government by resigning. Pol icy was set in liaison
conferences, often lasting hours, conducted among the Army and Navy officers,
in cabinet conferences including at least the prime minister and foreign
minister and service chiefs, and ultimately imperial conferences before Emperor
Hirohito and his household advisers.
18. Morley, Final
Confrontation, 175ff, 243.
19. Ibid., 261-65,
Appendix 9.
20. Ibid., 262 316;
Barnhart, japan Prepares, 254-59.
21. Barnhart, japan Prepares, 235, 260; FRUS, 1941,4:642-44; Hull,
Memoirs 2:1070.
22. Joseph P. Lash,
Roosevelt and Churchill, 1939-1941 (New York: Norton, 1976),457, 466-69.
23. Barnhart, japan Prepares, 235; Morley, Final Confrontation, 305,
317-20.
24. That day, when
FDR summoned the cabinet for the decision to freeze Japanese assets, he took
the extraordinary step of telling the American public that there was an odious
link between the predicted East Coast gasoline shortage and oil sales to Japan.
While addressing a volunteer group for civil defense headed by Mayor Fiorello
LaGuardia of New York-the city bearing the 1argest volume of risk for rationing
of gasoline-FDR told the press, You have been reading that the Secretary of the
Interior, as Oil Administrator, is faced with the problem of not having enough
gasoline to go around in the east coast, and how he is asking everybody to
curtail their consumption of gasoline. All right. Now, I am-I might be called
an American citizen living in Hyde Park, N.Y. And I say, "That's a funny
thing. Why am I asked to curtail my consumption of gasoline when I read in the
papers that thousands of tons of gasoline are going out from Los Angeles-west
coast-to Japan; and we are helping Japan in what looks like an act of
aggression." Roosevelt's linking of Atlantic and Pacific supplies was a
brazen political canard to guide public opinion and perhaps soothe Japanese
anger. There was no conceivable possibility of satisfying East Coast needs with
West Coast oil. Nevertheless, in the weeks following 26 July, as a relentless
oil embargo by means of the dollar freeze descended on Japan, Ickes continued
to insist, against the advice of government and private experts, against all
remedies offered by the industry, against the findings of a senatorial
investigating committee, and even against evidence that Britain did not need u.s. tankers, that an East Coast gasoline crisis was
inevitable. The specious rationale of a shortage continued almost to the eve of
Pearl Harbor: the United States could not spare California oil for Japan
because it was scarce in New York.
25. Ralph H. Davies,
Acting Petroleum Coordinator for National Defense, testimony, pt. I, 28 August,
I-52; letter from Davies, 4 September, 165-67; and Davies statement, 9 and 10
September 1941, 272-347, 356-80, all in Special Committee, Hearings.
26. Special
Committee, Hearings, pt. I, 29 August, 73-79; 8 September 1941, 215-39.
27. Ralph Budd, a transportation
advisor to the Council of National Defense, calculated 29,000 idle cars.
Statement, Special Committee Hearings, pt I, 4 September 1941.
28. John J. Pelley,
President of the Association of American Railroads, Statement and Testimony, 3
September, Special Committee, Hearings, pt. I, 81-II2; letter from Pelley, 5
September 194 I, 191-214; Statement and Testimony, 2 October, Special Committee,
Hearings, pt. 2, 605-38.
29. Special
Committee, Report No. 576, Gasoline and Fuel-Oil Shortages: Preliminary Report,
II September 194 I.
30. Harold L. Ickes,
Petroleum Coordinator for National Defense, Statement and Testimony of I
October 1941, Special Committee, Hearings, pt. 2, 383-593; Ickes, Secret Diary,
622-23.
31. Ickes, Secret
Diary, 630-32; Statement of Admiral Emory S. Land, Chairman, Maritime
Commission, 29 August 1941, Special Committee, Hearings, pt. 1,53-73; Senator
Francis Maloney, comment, I October 1941, Special Committee, Hearings, pt. 2,
574-75; Economist, 26 July 1941, cited in Special Committee, Hearings, pt. 1,28
August 1941, 354-55.
32. Oil and Gas
Journal, 30 October, 9,12,181941; 6 November 1941, 59; 20 November 1941,18; and
4 December 1941,16; Ickes, Secret Diary, 631-32. Pelley's claims were
ultimately justified. In April 1942, when German U-boats were sinking many
tankers off the Atlantic and Gulf coasts, the railroads moved six hundred
thousand barrels per day to the East Coast, a volume almost 50 percent of the
prewar rate of total supply for the region.
33. Payton-Smith,
Oil, 129, 162-63, 178-81, 195-211,375-79, Appendixes IV, VI; and Gas Journal, 9
October, 1941, 24.
34. Oil and Gas
Journal, 4 August 1941, 28, 80; 21 August 1941, 26; II September 1941, 14-15; 2
October 1941,16; 6 November 1941, 59, 66; 4 December 1941, 20.
35. The U.S. Library
of Congress catalog lists 115 books in English under "Pearl Harbor
Attack." Many address the diplomatic prelude rather than the attack
itself. A few espouse conspiracy theories.
36. National Archives
and Records Administration (NARA), Holocaust-Era Assets: A Finding Aid to
Records at the National Archives at College Park, Maryland (Washington, D.C.:
NARA, 1999). The files are in Office of Assistant Secretary for International Mfairs, RG 56, NA (hereafter cited as OASIA), and Records
of the Federal Reserve System, RG 82, NA. Secretary of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System to National Archives, Agreement to Transfer
Records and accompanying letter, 23 January 1997; and Greg Bradsher to author,
e-mail, 26 January 2007, both in author's files.
37. Record 3, no. 4
(May 1997); William W. Stiles, Secretary of the Board of Governors to Assistant
Archivist for Records Services, National Archives, de classifications agreement
and letter, 23 January 1997.
For updates click homepage here